• Tools and Resources
  • Customer Services
  • Business Education
  • Business Law
  • Business Policy and Strategy
  • Entrepreneurship
  • Human Resource Management
  • Information Systems
  • International Business
  • Negotiations and Bargaining
  • Operations Management
  • Organization Theory
  • Organizational Behavior
  • Problem Solving and Creativity
  • Research Methods
  • Social Issues
  • Technology and Innovation Management
  • Share This Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Article contents

Institutional theory in organization studies.

  • Robert J. David , Robert J. David Department of Management, McGill University
  • Pamela S. Tolbert Pamela S. Tolbert Department of Organizational Behavior, Cornell University
  •  and  Johnny Boghossian Johnny Boghossian Department of Management, Laval University
  • https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190224851.013.158
  • Published online: 23 December 2019

Institutional theory is a prominent perspective in contemporary organizational research. It encompasses a large, diverse body of theoretical and empirical work connected by a common emphasis on cultural understandings and shared expectations. Institutional theory is often used to explain the adoption and spread of formal organizational structures, including written policies, standard practices, and new forms of organization. Tracing its roots to the writings of Max Weber on legitimacy and authority, the perspective originated in the 1950s and 1960s with the work of Talcott Parsons, Philip Selznick, and Alvin Gouldner on organization–environment relations. It subsequently underwent a “cognitive turn” in the 1970s, with an emphasis on taken-for-granted habits and assumptions, and became commonly known as “neo-institutionalism” in organizational studies. Recently, work based on the perspective has shifted from a focus on processes involved in producing isomorphism to a focus on institutional change, exemplified by studies of the emergence of new laws and regulations, products, services, and occupations. The expansion of the theoretical framework has contributed to its long-term vitality, though a number of challenges to its development remain, including resolving inconsistencies in the different models of decision-making and action ( homo economicus vs. homo sociologicus ) that underpin institutional analysis and improving our understanding of the intersection of socio-cultural forces and entrepreneurial agency.

  • institutional theory
  • institutional entrepreneurship
  • institutional logics
  • institutional change
  • market categories
  • organizational forms
  • organizational structure

In contemporary organization studies, research under the banner of institutional theory encompasses a large body of theoretical and empirical work connected by a common emphasis on social norms and shared expectations as key sources of organizations’ structures, actions, and outcomes. While institutional theory is widely recognized as one of the most prominent approaches to organizational research today (David & Bitektine, 2009 ; Greenwood, Oliver, Sahlin, & Suddaby, 2008 ), substantial differences exist among scholars about both the referents of key concepts and the core assumptions regarding how social norms and expectations affect organizations. For example, some use “institution” to denote a specific organizational practice or requirement (Meyer & Rowan, 1977 ), while others use the term to refer to whole organizations (Selznick, 1949 ) or to broad systems of norms and values that characterize a given sector of society (Friedland & Alford, 1991 ). Likewise, classic formulations have been criticized as providing little or no room for individual agency (DiMaggio, 1988 ), while others assert that key arguments (e.g., about decoupling) imply highly strategic actors (Tolbert & Zucker, 1996 ).

This overview of institutional theory in organization studies begins with a general summary of key ideas and arguments from foundational work in this tradition. 1 This is followed by a discussion of two research streams that arose from the critiques and controversies that developed around the concepts and implicit theoretical assumptions contained in foundational work: one on institutional entrepreneurship and the other on institutional logics. Two areas of inquiry garnering increasing attention within the tradition—the emergence of new market categories and the role of the state in institutional change—are then discussed. Some thoughts about the continued promise and attractiveness of the perspective and suggestions for further theoretical and empirical development are offered in conclusion.

Foundations

Early analyses of organizations by sociologists used the term “institutional” to refer broadly to aspects of organizations involved in mediating relations with external constituencies, and more specifically to securing favorable perceptions of an organization by constituents as a way, ultimately, of ensuring flows of necessary resources. This is exemplified in an early statement by a key proponent of structural-functionalist theory, Talcott Parsons ( 1956 ), who elaborated a “cultural-institutional” view of organizations in the first issue of the Administrative Science Quarterly . Parsons ( 1956 , p. 67) argued that, as components of a larger social system (society), organizations need to demonstrate “basic acceptance of the more generalized values of the superordinate system.” In this context, he distinguished three broad organizational levels, each with distinctive functions: technical (production activities), managerial (coordination and control), and institutional (managing external relations) (Parsons, 1960 ). In Parsons’s view, the institutional level was critical to articulating the connection between an organization’s espoused goals and the functioning of the larger society, thus providing the organization with general legitimacy—a process that would become a central theme in institutional research on organizations.

Philip Selznick ( 1957 ), drawing on both Parsons’s work and Barnard’s ( 1938 ) earlier analysis of the functions of top management, amplified this argument by identifying institutionalization as a key task of organizational leaders. In his exposition, institutionalization entailed linking an organization to larger societal values in the public’s mind, thus enhancing its long-run survival. “Organizations become infused with value as they come to symbolize the community’s aspirations, its sense of identity … An organization that does take on this symbolic meaning has some claim on the community to avoid liquidation or transformation on purely technical or economic grounds” (Selznick, 1957 , p. 19). Thus, Selznick equates “institution” to an organization that has come to be seen as embodying key societal values (Kraatz & Flores, 2015 ). His emphasis on leaders’ role in this process reflects his earlier research (Selznick, 1949 ) on the highly contentious founding of an organization by the U.S. government in the 1930s, the Tennessee Valley Authority (TVA). Characterized as the country’s only serious flirtation with socialism (Perrow, 1972 ), at the outset the TVA faced strong criticism from political opponents, leading it to focus on one element of its mandate, embodying grassroots democracy in its governance structure, thus tying itself to a basic societal value.

This approach to organizational analysis was largely eclipsed from the late 1950s through the 1970s by the rise of what came to be known as contingency theory (Donaldson, 2001 ). Scholars in this tradition focused on explaining variations in different aspects of organizations’ formal structure, relying (at least implicitly) on a few key theoretical assumptions (Schoonhoven, 1981 ). One was that elements of formal structure in an organization, such as average job specialization, codification of work procedures, and the relative proportion of supervisors to line workers, resulted from efforts to maximize the efficiency of production activities. A second assumption was that the efficiency of particular structures depended on (i.e., was contingent on) organizational attributes such as the size and dominant technology of an organization (see Scott, 1975 ). By the 1970s, an increasing number of studies in this tradition had begun to shift focus from internal organizational attributes to environmental relations as important contingencies, but the underlying theoretical assumptions of earlier work were retained (e.g., Lawrence & Lorsch, 1967 ): formal structure was treated as the outcome of decisions by autonomous actors, driven primarily by concerns of efficient production.

In the late 1970s, a now-classic paper by Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 ) significantly challenged this view, marking the beginning of contemporary institutional theory, sometimes denoted as “neo-institutional theory.” A key insight underpinned their analysis, namely that formal structures have symbolic properties as well as action-generating ones. Thus, specific structures—for example, formalized hiring requirements (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983 ), a human resources office (Baron, Dobbin, & Jennings, 1986 ), or a chief financial officer (Zorn, 2004 )—can be invested with cultural meaning, signifying values such as rationality, equal opportunity, or the importance of shareholders as a constituency. Under this condition, organizations may adopt such structures as a way of signaling a commitment to the associated values. Importantly, and in contrast to Selznick’s ( 1957 ) older conception of “institutions” as specific organizations that had acquired the patina of broad social values, post-Meyer and Rowan, the term came to be identified with particular sub-organizational elements of formal structure (policies, practices, job titles, etc.) that had such a patina. Such elements could diffuse across communities of organizations, a process that attracted considerable empirical attention within institutional theory. The diffusion of elements was equated with their “institutionalization,” now used to refer to increasing acceptance of an element as an appropriate component of well-managed, legitimate organizations. Thus, diffusion and institutionalization were theorized to be reinforcing: as more organizations adopted a particular structural element, it gained greater social acceptance (became progressively institutionalized). This, in turn, led to increasing conformity pressures on organizations that had not yet adopted it to do so, accelerating its diffusion (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983 ). These arguments were reflected in a spate of studies examining the diffusion of various practices across organizations (e.g., Baron et al., 1986 ; Zorn, 2004 ; Okhmatovskiy & David, 2012 ) but were soon to be challenged as insufficiently nuanced because they neglected consideration of forces mitigating against such pressures for increased diffusion (Abrahamson, 1996 ; Ahmadjian & Robinson, 2001 ; David & Strang, 2006 ; Oliver, 1991 , 1992 ).

In sharp contrast to the then-dominant approach of contingency theory, this approach implied that the creation of formal structures in an organization may be independent of any concern related to quality or costs of production. It also challenged the assumption, common to economics-based explanations of organizational behavior, that efficiency and quality of output are necessarily the most important determinants of organizational survival (see Meyer & Zucker, 1989 ; Sine, David, & Mitsuhashi, 2007 ; Zucker, 1983 ).

Similarly, it directed organizational scholars’ attention to external factors unrelated to production processes, such as the passage of legislation, political pressure by social movement activists, and the development of strong norms within an organizational network, in explaining formal structure. In this context, DiMaggio and Powell ( 1983 ) argued for more attention by researchers to forces producing high levels of homogeneity among organizations rather than those producing variation. Elaborating on Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 , pp. 347–348), they identified three key forces. One was coercive pressures, often created by government-sponsored mandates that affect organizations, but also by the demands of powerful, resource-controlling organizations. A second was imitative pressures, resulting from decision-makers’ reliance on other organizations’ observed behavior as a guide for their own organization. The third was normative pressure, social expectations generated through the implicit or explicit lobbying efforts of professionals and other actors for the adoption of particular policies and practices. In fact, as Zucker ( 1977 ) showed in a lab experiment using the autokinetic effect, conformity pressures of this kind could be produced in organizations with relative ease. Scott ( 1995 ) expanded further on these pressures for homogenization, describing three “pillars” of institutions, which he labeled regulatory, cultural-cognitive, and normative. Notably, DiMaggio and Powell’s ( 1983 , p. 148) theory of organizational homogeneity directed attention to the “organizational field” as both a construct and a unit of analysis. Fields, defined as the “totality of relevant actors” surrounding any focal organization or constituting any sphere of organizational life, thus became a potential object of study for institutional theorists.

This approach to thinking about organizations fit well with the growing interest of scholars in exploring environmental relations as sources of organizations’ actions, and meshed with a cumulating body of work on organizational decision-making that stressed inherent limits on decision-makers’ ability to make highly rational choices (Cyert & March, 1963 ; March & Simon, 1958 ; Simon, 1947 ; Weick, 1969 ). In this context, the rapid acceptance and spread of institutional theory as a framework for organizational analysis is perhaps unsurprising. Its continued dominance in the field of organizational studies is evinced in a variety of ways. For example, three foundational studies in this tradition—by Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 ), Zucker ( 1977 ), and DiMaggio and Powell ( 1983 )—have garnered over 70,000 citations to date, according to Google Scholar. Likewise, a steady stream of special journal issues and edited volumes dedicated to the tradition attests to its continued vitality (e.g., Dacin, Goodstein, & Scott, 2002 ; Greenwood et al., 2008 ; Greenwood, Oliver, Lawrence, & Meyer, 2017 ; Powell & DiMaggio, 1991 ; Zucker, 1988 ).

In part, institutional theory’s continued prominence reflects extensions of the framework over time, aimed at addressing perceived problems and limitations of early theoretical formulations. These generated a number of different streams of work, most notably work on institutional entrepreneurship and institutional logics.

Institutional Entrepreneurship

One of the earliest critiques of foundational work was offered by DiMaggio ( 1988 , p. 4), concerning institutional theory’s inattention to the problem of “agency.” In his words, “institutional theory has no explicit or formal theory of the role that interests play in institutionalization and … [thus] distracts attention from the ways in which variations in the strategies and practices of goal-directed actors may be related to variation in organizational structures, practices and forms.” As he noted, in part, this problem reflects the incorporation of a phenomenological perspective on social interaction (e.g., Berger & Luckmann, 1967 ; Garfinkel, 1967 ) into theoretical arguments. For phenomenologists, a key issue is to explain how social interaction can be sustained over time. Explanations typically emphasize processes through which individuals develop shared interpretations of particular behaviors, and the way in which such shared meanings serve to constrain behavior. The constraining effects occur in part because the behaviors become habitual (taken for granted), and in part because actors seek to avoid anticipated negative social reactions to nonconformity. Foundational work in institutional theory often referenced phenomenological arguments in explaining why organizations adopted practices once they had reached some threshold of institutionalization (see DiMaggio & Powell, 1983 ; Meyer & Rowan, 1977 ; Tolbert & Zucker, 1983 ; Zucker, 1977 ).

It is worth noting that Meyer and Rowan’s ( 1977 , pp. 356–357) discussion of decoupling, suggesting that organizations are apt to segregate or minimize the impact of institutionalized structures on day-to-day organizational activities and operations (thus treating them as largely ceremonial), implies a high degree of strategic behavior by organizational decision-makers. How this strategic view could be reconciled with a phenomenological emphasis is not made clear in their work, however, as Tolbert and Zucker ( 1996 ) observed.

To rectify this limitation, DiMaggio proposed a focus on studying institutionalization processes (rather than consequences). He urged that such processes be treated as a “product of the political efforts of actors to accomplish their ends” ( 1988 , p. 13) and called on researchers to recognize that “the success of the institutionalization project and the form that the resulting institution takes depend on the relative power of the actors who support, oppose, or otherwise strive to influence it.” This call to arms laid the foundation for a line of work on “institutional entrepreneurship,” typically concerned with the purposeful activities of individuals and groups that lead (directly or indirectly) to the adoption of various policies and practices by organizational targets, or even the founding of entirely new forms of organizations.

Empirical work on institutional entrepreneurship began in earnest only in the 2000s, however, starting with a notable special issue on institutional change in the Academy of Management Journal (Dacin et al., 2002 ). In that special issue, Zilber ( 2002 ) conceptualized institutionalization as “an interplay between actions, meanings, and actors” and showed how times of crisis provide opportunities for agency and institutional change. In a now well-cited paper, Greenwood, Suddaby, and Hinings ( 2002 ) developed a process model for institutional change driven by institutional entrepreneurs, using the case of field-level change in the accounting profession in Canada. Building on the conceptual work of Strang and Meyer ( 1993 ) and Tolbert and Zucker ( 1996 ), they argued that the core activity of institutional entrepreneurs is theorization, or “the rendering of ideas into understandable and compelling formats” (Greenwood et al., 2002 , p. 75). In their study, large accounting firms (the institutional entrepreneurs) justified changes in the structures and activities of accounting firms in general by exposing contradictions in the accounting field’s rationales for existing practices and emphasizing how those changes were aligned with the profession’s prevailing values. In a similar way, Maguire, Hardy, and Lawrence ( 2004 , pp. 669, 671) described how institutional entrepreneurs in the emerging HIV/AIDS treatment field theorized new practices of consultation and information exchange between community organizations and pharmaceutical firms by “assembling a wide array of arguments that translate the interests of diverse stakeholders” and by building coalitions of these stakeholders through “bargaining, negotiation, and compromise.”

More recently, David, Sine, and Haveman ( 2013 ) developed a model of institutional entrepreneurship directed at legitimating new forms of organization in emerging fields. Significantly, these authors argued that institutional entrepreneurship involves more than persuasive discourse and includes building affiliations and engaging in collective action. Empirically, they showed how the proponents of early management consulting organizations affiliated with prestigious universities, scientific communities, and social elites to gain legitimacy. These proponents of “professional” management consulting also created an association to “collectively define a social code of prescribed and proscribed behaviors” that contrasted with those of competing forms and provided a template for replication (David et al., 2013 , p. 370). Building on these ideas, Canales ( 2016 , p. 1548) explained how actors promoting the small and medium enterprise credit market in Mexico engaged in “work to suspend existing institutions” and “recruit allies, find resources, experiment with new practices, coordinate strategies of action, and build political toolkits.” In summary, institutional entrepreneurship has become closely associated with institutional change projects driven by actors exercising agency in the pursuit of their interests. As a vibrant area of research (see Hardy & Maguire [ 2017 ] for a full review), it has largely overcome the critique that agency is underexplored within institutional theory. 2

Institutional Logics

In their generative paper, Friedland and Alford ( 1991 ) questioned institutional theory’s importation of an assumption made by structural-functionalists about the general congruence of social values. Foundational papers by Zucker ( 1977 ) and by Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 ) had implied a shared commitment to a particular social value—rationality—as an underlying precondition of the institutionalization of organizational practices, but Friedland and Alford argued that institutionalized practices could rest on a variety of values, which could in fact conflict with one another. This provided a key point of departure for a growing literature on institutional logics.

Similar to structural-functionalist theorists, Friedland and Alford proposed a view of society as constituted by different sectors (e.g., economic, political, familial, etc.), each characterized by a distinctive “institutional logic,” in their words. Comprising both material practices and symbolic constructions, logics provide organizing principles, or broad guidelines for action (Friedland & Alford, 1991 , p. 248). In contrast to previous work, however, they suggested that not all logics were necessarily compatible ( 1991 , p. 248): “The institutional logic of capitalism is accumulation and the commodification of human activity. That of the state is rationalization … That of democracy is participation … That of the family is community …” Such competing logics offer a basis for individuals to perceive and justify resistance to a prevailing structural arrangement, and to propose alternatives that reflect a different institutional logic.

These arguments provided a foundation for a large stream of organizational studies that illuminate the existence of multiple logics within different communities, and examine tensions stemming from the coexistence of competing logics within a given organization (Greenwood et al., 2011 ; Kraatz & Block, 2008 ). Early research in this area focused on how one logic replaces another. In a landmark paper, Thornton and Ocasio ( 1999 , p. 804) explained how the dominant logic in the U.S. higher education publishing field changed from an editorial to a market focus, and how this affected changes in executive succession. Rao, Monin, and Durand ( 2003 ) described how a logic of “nouvelle cuisine” replaced one of “haute cuisine” in French gastronomy, while Sine and David ( 2003 ) explained how a natural monopoly logic was replaced by an entrepreneurial logic in the field of electricity generation.

Other notable research has focused not on logic replacement but instead on logic coexistence. In his study of mutual funds, Lounsbury ( 2007 , p. 302) showed how the “trustee logic” (originating in Boston) and the “performance logic” (originating in New York) provided “distinct forms of rationality that informed the behavior of different kinds of mutual funds” and “facilitated the creation of variation in the subpopulation of professional money management firms” (i.e., growth versus non-growth funds). Also highlighting geographic differences in logics, Greenwood, Díaz, Li, and Lorente ( 2010 ) described how regional logics and family logics impact organizational responses to an overarching market logic. Specifically, in their study of Spanish manufacturing firms, they concluded that poorer-performing organizations downsize more readily than more successful firms, indicating the significance of the market logic, but that at the same time the state and family logics temper the influence of the market logic.

In their study of state offices of dispute resolution, Purdy and Gray ( 2009 ) identified conditions that enabled multiple practices supported by conflicting logics (judicial logic, social services logic) to be institutionalized, including the presence of multiple resource pools associated with different institutional actors and the lack of a dominant, overarching regulatory or professional framework that could impose field-level standards. Reay and Hinings ( 2009 ) elaborated on the “mechanisms of collaboration” in Alberta health care that allowed the conflicting logics of business-like health care and medical professionalism to coexist. Also focusing on the medical field, Dunn and Jones ( 2010 , p. 114) found that the “plural logics of care and science in medical education are supported by distinct groups and interests, fluctuate over time, and create dynamic tensions about how to educate future professionals.” They concluded that in fields where distinct logics are needed yet advocated by different groups, these logics may oscillate over time rather than reach a state of dominance.

Finally, a more recent but burgeoning stream of research at the intra-organizational level has examined the presence of multiple logics within organizations. In a theory piece, Besharov and Smith ( 2014 ) proposed a framework for categorizing types of logic multiplicity within firms based on two key dimensions: (1) the degree of consistency in the logics’ prescriptions for actions (“compatibility”) and (2) the extent to which practices tied to different logics are central to organizational functioning (“centrality”). Organizations that comprise logics with low compatibility but high centrality are often dubbed “hybrid” organizations (Battilana & Dorado, 2010 ; Besharov & Smith, 2014 ; Jay, 2012 ; Pache & Santos, 2013 ) and have been the subject of recent research on how tensions arising from logic conflict are managed. One approach focuses on integrating logics (Battilana & Dorado, 2010 ), for example by developing performance metrics (Mair, Mayer, & Lutz, 2015 ), incentive systems (Battilana & Lee, 2014 ; Ebrahim, Battilana, & Mair, 2014 ), product designs (Dalpiaz, Rindova, & Ravasi, 2016 ), and organizational identities (Battilana & Dorado, 2010 ) that do not reflect any one of the prevailing logics but rather combine logics in ways unique to the organization. Another approach focuses on structural differentiation (Greenwood, Raynard, Kodeih, Micelotta, & Lounsbury, 2011 ), whereby organizations segregate logics into different organizational elements, but find unique and creative ways to assure mutual understanding and collaboration across the elements (Battilana & Lee, 2014 ; Battilana, Sengul, Pache, & Model, 2015 ; Smets, Jarzabkowski, Burke, & Spee, 2015 ). For example, Pache and Santos ( 2013 , p. 972) found that “organizations selectively coupled intact elements prescribed by each logic … allow[ing] them to project legitimacy to external stakeholders without having to engage in costly deceptions or negotiations.”

Building on this research, Ramus, Vaccaro, and Brusoni ( 2017 ) suggested that it is the combination of collaboration and formalization that allows organizations to successfully reconcile the conflicting demands arising from multiple logics; specifically, logic integration can be enabled by an initial phase of formalizing and separating each competing logic, followed by building collaboration (Ramus et al., 2017 , p. 1254). More recently, Smith and Besharov ( 2019 ) explained how logic hybridity within organizations can be sustained over time through a combination of continually developing novel approaches to ongoing tensions while at the same time maintaining stable features that act to bound these adaptive processes.

New Market Categories

While the research streams on institutional entrepreneurship and institutional logics are now large and well developed, institutional theorists have more recently turned their attention to the question of how new market categories emerge. Defined as “economic exchange structure[s] among producers and consumers” (Navis & Glynn, 2010 , p. 441), market categories represent consensus over labels and meanings among the actors and audiences involved (Durand & Paolella, 2013 ; Kennedy, 2008 ). In studying new market categories, institutional theorists often invoke research from the two former streams on institutional logics and institutional entrepreneurship, as well as theory on social movements. In this research, new market categories are seen as emerging through a process of social construction, whereby collections of objects—products or services—come to be perceived as being “of the same type” or close substitutes for each other (Durand & Boulogne, 2017 ; Glynn & Navis, 2013 ; Navis & Glynn, 2010 , p. 440).

Social movements have been seen as generative of new market categories. In an early elucidation of this process, Swaminathan and Wade ( 2001 ) argued that social movements help create new markets by providing collective action frames and by facilitating resource mobilization by entrepreneurs. Building on this idea, Lounsbury, Ventresca, and Hirsch ( 2003 ) described how the social movement promoting recycling practices contributed to changes in interorganizational relations and discourse that altered the existing U.S. solid waste management field, thereby enabling the emergence of a for-profit recycling industry. Weber, Heinze, and DeSoucey ( 2008 , p. 543) showed how the social movement for grass-fed beef motivated entrepreneurs to produce this product and increased their commitment in the face of obstacles because they “obtained emotional energy from connecting their work to a sense of self and moral values” represented by the movement. Hiatt, Sine, and Tolbert ( 2009 ) described how the Temperance Movement in the United States at once deinstitutionalized breweries, created demand for a new category of “soft” drinks, and increased the availability of resources for entrepreneurs in the nascent category. Sine and Lee ( 2009 ) showed how the environmental movement mobilized members and non-members alike to support the emerging wind power sector.

In sum, institutional theory suggests social movement actors can promote shared notions of the kinds of organizational activities that are “right” through proselytizing and other techniques of moral suasion; this can motivate entrepreneurs who are sympathetic to the values of a given movement, persuade consumers to accept certain products and services as valuable (thus creating market opportunities that even non-sympathizing entrepreneurs may pursue), and affect policies and create infrastructures that facilitate certain entrepreneurial activities (Tolbert, David, & Sine, 2011 ).

A related thread of research takes a more actively social-constructivist view of new market categories and sees the emergence of a new category as the purposeful creation of common meanings and identities (Glynn & Navis, 2013 ; Jones, Maoret, Massa, & Svejenova, 2012 ; Pontikes & Kim, 2017 ). In this vein, Wry, Lounsbury, and Glynn ( 2011 , p. 450) focus on the “collective identity stories” employed by entrepreneurial actors to help project an image of themselves “as a coherent category with a meaningful label and identity.” The identity claims of entrepreneurs are evaluated by other field actors, who then accord (or not) resources and legitimacy to the new category. As such, entrepreneurs in new market categories who elaborate identities that are both distinct from those of existing categories yet aligned with prevalent “institutional understandings” are more likely to receive favorable judgments from investors (Hargadon & Douglas, 2001 ; Navis & Glynn, 2011 ). For example, in their research on the emergence of satellite radio as a new market category, Glynn and Navis ( 2010 ; see also Navis & Glynn, 2010 ) analyzed the public statements of executives from start-up firms XM and Sirius, and found these statements helped construct a distinctive identity for new ventures, and, in the process, lent credibility to the nascent market category. Khaire and Wadhwani ( 2010 , p. 1281) explained how art historians and critics shaped the construction of meaning in the Modern Indian Art category by “reinterpreting historical constructs in ways that enhanced commensurability and enabled aesthetic comparisons and valuation.”

It is important to note, however, that identity building and legitimation in new market categories can involve more than persuasive discourse from producers. David et al. ( 2013 ) identified a number of symbolic elements deployed by entrepreneurs in the early management consulting industry to legitimate their identity as “professionals,” such as ties to prestigious universities and scientific associations. Similarly, Khaire ( 2014 ) found that entrepreneurs in the emergent high-end fashion industry in India incorporated traditional textiles and clothing styles to signal that their activities were consistent with “ancient skills and traditions,” thereby increasing acceptance among a population skeptical of elitist fashion. And sometimes, “empty” categories are created by actors other than producers, only to be filled (or not) by the latter. Sine and David ( 2003 ) showed how regulators in the United States created the category of “alternative electricity producer” through legislation, a category that was later filled with thousands of small producers. Edman and Ahmadjian ( 2017 ) described how external actors—including the media, think tanks, local prefectural governments, consultants, and tourism companies—created the “ji-biru” (local beer) market category in Japan. This category, however, failed to develop a clear meaning, and was eventually eclipsed by the craft beer category.

The Role of the State in Institutional Change

The state figured prominently in early institutional accounts of organizations, dating back to Selznick’s ( 1949 ) discussion of the pivotal role of the state in the founding and development of the TVA. Building on Weber ( 1978 ), neo-institutionalists subsequently conceptualized the state as the primary rationalizer of social life, particularly in disseminating the bureaucratic organizational form. In their seminal paper, Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 , p. 342) explained that “one of the central problems in organization theory is to describe the conditions that give rise to rationalized formal structure,” and proposed the quest for legitimacy as the cause of rationalization, of which the centralized state was the primary vehicle. In a similar vein, DiMaggio and Powell argued that through the enactment and enforcement of laws and regulations, the state is among the “great rationalizers of the second half of the twentieth century” (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983 , p. 147). In their discussion of institutional logics, Friedland and Alford ( 1991 , p. 248) included the state logic among the central logics of Western societies and defined it as the “rationalization and the regulation of human activity by legal and bureaucratic hierarchies.”

The role of the state has received renewed attention in recent years, and contemporary research has discussed its capacity to act on all three “pillars” of institutionalization identified by (Scott, 1995 ): regulative, normative, and cognitive. From the standpoint of the regulative pillar, the state has the capacity to define the rules of the game by enacting laws and regulations. State policies and regulations have been credited with the development of a wide variety of industries, including railroads (Dobbin & Dowd, 1997 ), farm wineries (Swaminathan, 1995 ), and wind power (Sine & Lee, 2009 ). Anti-trust laws and interventionist policies affect firms’ cooperative and competitive behaviors (Fligstein, 1990 , 1996 ; Haveman, Russo, & Meyer, 2001 ; Mezias & Boyle, 2005 ). The state can dictate the scope of firm activity by codifying industry boundaries, which affect inter-industry competition (Amburgey, Dacin, & Kelly, 1994 ; Dobbin & Dowd, 2000 ; Haveman, 1993 ; Haveman et al., 2001 ). Changes in laws or regulations can also lead to changes in the distribution of organizational forms: Sine, Haveman, and Tolbert ( 2005 ) showed that a law requiring electric utilities to purchase and distribute power from independent power plants in the heavily regulated U.S. power industry increased founding of independent power plants, especially those using novel technologies. Dowell and David ( 2011 ) found that the number of private liquor stores in Alberta increased dramatically in the wake of an abrupt regulatory change. Closer to the internal functioning of organizations, the state may demand the adoption of specific organizational practices (Tolbert & Zucker, 1983 ) or codes of behavior (Okhmatovskiy & David, 2012 ), or may require particular outcomes without specifying the means by which they are to be achieved (Chuang, Church, & Ophir, 2011 ; Dobbin & Sutton, 1998 ; Kelly, 2003 ).

In terms of the normative pillar, the state has the capacity to confer sociopolitical legitimacy, which represents an evaluation of fit with prevailing norms and values (Aldrich & Fiol, 1994 ; Bitektine, 2011 ). This may take the form of state-sponsored certifications (Baum & Oliver, 1991 , 1992 ; Sine et al., 2005 ). For example, Sine et al. ( 2007 ) found that in the emergent independent power sector, projects having a government-issued certification—which was purely symbolic and could have been obtained by any qualified firm for a nominal fee—were more likely to reach the start-up phase. The state may even legitimate by its own patterns of consumption, as was the case for management consulting during the early years of that profession, when the state represented an important client for consultants (David, 2012 ).

Finally, in terms of the cognitive pillar, the state can influence the classification schemes by which we apprehend and organize the social world. This is most evident in the context of nascent markets, where entrepreneurs may lack even the basic vocabularies to define the contours of their markets and convey the value of their novel products, to hesitant investors, partners, and employees alike (Aldrich & Fiol, 1994 ). If, as discussed previously, new market categories rely on some degree of consensus among market participants, by virtue of its powerful position the state can promote such consensus and allow market construction to proceed. For example, during the emergence of the market for cochlear implants, there were two competing approaches to the technology, each informed by different sets of values and beliefs with regard to deafness (Garud, 2008 ). Ultimately, the National Institutes of Health in the United States played a central role in shaping the market that later developed, including through conferences that led to the dominance of one technology and the marginalization of the other (Garud, 2008 ). When states regulate and codify nascent spheres of organizational activity as distinct market categories, the organizations that comprise them enjoy greater audience attention and access to resources (Sine & David, 2003 ). Returning to the independent power example cited previously, in their selection of the projects that would qualify under a government program, government administrators drew the boundaries of the “independent power” category by defining the types of technologies the new category would come to encompass (Sine et al., 2007 ).

Conclusion and Suggestions for Future Research

While the substantive foci of studies drawing upon institutional theory are wide-ranging, there are common assumptions and preoccupations reflected in the work we have described. One key connecting theme is the importance of understanding ideational or cultural sources of existing organizational arrangements and of organizational change. This theme ties work in this tradition to a Weberian approach ( 1978 ) to studying social phenomena, and distinguishes it from more economic-based approaches that emphasize constraining market demands for efficiently produced goods and services as critical influences. As we noted, the relative neglect of the influence of social norms and interpretations in organizational analyses from the late 1950s onward (when organizational studies began to evolve as a distinctive area of social sciences) helps to account for the receptivity of researchers to institutional theory in the late 1970s, and for its continued popularity today as an alternative to more materialist approaches.

While both approaches offer valid insights into organizational phenomena, they have yet to be integrated or reconciled and are rarely, if ever, adopted simultaneously in a given analysis. This may be due to differences in underlying assumptions about the nature of individual decision-making and action on which each approach rests, differences captured by the (satirically offered) distinction between homo economicus and homo sociologicus (Dahrendorf, 1968 ). The former term denotes a view of individuals as continually calculating, interest-maximizing actors, while the latter rests on an opposing view, non-optimizing, habit-following actors who are driven largely by commitments to internalized values.

Critiques and extensions of institutional theory often reflect concerns that original formulations rested too much on the latter view (DiMaggio, 1988 ; Oliver, 1991 ). (One could quibble about whether conformity to social expectations is not agentic, though it is an unlikely response of powerful actors who are pursuing arrangements that enhance their own interests.) The streams of work we have described on institutional entrepreneurship and institutional logics have sought to address this concern. Work on institutional entrepreneurship has provided a much more elaborate answer to a critical question for the institutional perspective: how are institutions created and changed? Likewise, studies based on the notion of competing logics provide an explanation for variation in structural arrangements and forms of organization within the general framework of institutional theory. Thus, both streams have added substantially to the general theoretical perspective.

But important questions, ones relating to the role of agency within the perspective (i.e., the integration of homo economicus and homo sociologicus models of action), remain. Work on institutional entrepreneurship struggles to identify the key conditions under which individuals are most likely to transcend the constraints of cultural prescriptions and envision alternative arrangements, and the conditions under which others are likely to embrace such alternative visions (rather than sanctioning such entrepreneurs as wild-eyed deviants). (For notable exceptions, see Seo & Creed [ 2002 ] and Lawrence & Suddaby [ 2006 ].) Similarly, the conditions under which actors can successfully promote a given logic as a viable competitor to an existing logic, or when actors might subscribe to a logic that is not aligned with their interests (per Marx’s notion of false consciousness), remain to be addressed.

We suggest that progress in answering these questions may come from explicit theorizing across (as opposed to within) the four streams we have outlined here. For example, elucidating the strength of prevailing institutional logics and the presence of conflicting logics in studies of institutional entrepreneurship would contextualize such activities and avoid accounts of unbridled agency. Conversely, a better understanding of the agency that occurs during logic conflict can provide a fuller account of how institutional logics evolve at the field level. In brief, studies that offer full accounts of agency (institutional entrepreneurship) while at the same time accounting for institutional context (logics and their interaction) may be best positioned to avoid the caricatures of homo economicus and homo sociologicus .

Similarly, work that bridges research on the state, or more broadly on political processes, and research on institutional entrepreneurship seems potentially fruitful. Currently, reassertions of national sovereignty, such as Brexit, are challenging previously unquestioned institutions involving globalized trade, immigration, and long-standing international relations. This opens interesting avenues of inquiry for institutional theorists. How might such political changes cascade down to the organizational level? For example, because market categories can become vehicles for national identity, as is the case for many foods in Europe (DeSoucey, 2010 ) and country music in the United States (Peterson, 1997 ), we may find corporate and political interests collaborating to strategically activate patriotic sentiment, as in the case of NASCAR (Newman & Giardina, 2010 ). The formulation of international strategies may be influenced by perceived historical ties between nations (Cooper, Greenwood, Hinings, & Brown, 1998 ), opposition to acquisitions by foreign firms may mount if nationalist sentiment is stirred (Riad & Vaara, 2011 ; Tienari, Vaara, & Björkman, 2003 ; Vaara & Tienari, 2002 ), and post-acquisition success may depend on overcoming nationalistic biases among international employees (Ailon-Souday & Kunda, 2003 ; Vaara & Tienari, 2011 ). As such, beliefs about the role of the state and the “nation” it represents can have far-reaching implications that have largely gone understudied. And more generally, in a context of increasing interest in corporate political activity (Mellahi, Frynas, Sun, & Siegel, 2016 ), future scholarly work may investigate how market actors attempt to influence state policies, or the diverse ways the state may then favor some sets of market actors over others.

As neo-institutional theory enters its fifth decade since Meyer and Rowan ( 1977 ), we marvel at its growth and resilience as a perspective while at the same time wondering how it might continue to thrive. As other prominent approaches within organization theory—contingency theory and population ecology come to mind—have lost vigor, how might institutional theory remain vibrant? The following three pieces of advice may help.

First, clarity (and possibly restraint) is needed in the use of the terms “institution” and “institutional.” Studies should be clear about what the focal institution is, its basis for institutionalization, and the social setting in which it is institutionalized. This should include clarity about level of analysis—is the institution under study an organization, organization form, sub-organizational element, or inter-organizational structure? And of course, scholars should resist using the label institutional when doing so provides little theoretical traction.

Second, institutional scholars must not lose sight of the tangible impact of institutions and institutionalization. Often enthralled by rich descriptions of historical processes, institutionalists should emphasize the practical relevance of their studies, whether for managers, policymakers, or societal outcomes. For example, if new market categories require consensus on meanings and labels, the state can promote such consensus through regulated certification systems, or alternatively, emergent industries may pursue consensus through self-regulation.

Finally, institutional theory must maintain its unifying focus on cultural forces as key drivers of organizational behaviors and outcomes. Indeed, institutional theorists are often alone in schools of business/management in their cultural approach to organizations, while their colleagues in functional areas—finance, marketing, strategy, operations management, and so forth—emphasize organizational efficiency as both an independent and a dependent variable. Institutional theory’s prominence, and we believe its future, lie in serving as a compelling and coherent counterpoint to this “cult of efficiency.” 3

Further Reading

  • Dacin, M. T. , Goodstein J. , & Scott, W. R. (2002). Institutional theory and institutional change: Introduction to the special research forum. Academy of Management Journal , 45 , 43–46.
  • David, R. J. , & Bitektine, A. (2009). The deinstitutionalization of institutional theory? Exploring divergent agendas in institutional research. In D. Buchanan & A. Bryman (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational research methods (pp. 160–175). London: SAGE.
  • Durand, R. , & Boulongne, R. (2017). Advancing category research: Theoretical mapping and under-researched areas. In R. Greenwood , C. Oliver , T. B. Lawrence , & R. E. Meyer (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism (2nd ed., pp. 647–668). London: SAGE.
  • Durand, R. , & Paolella, L. (2013). Category stretching: Reorienting research on categories in strategy, entrepreneurship, and organization theory. Journal of Management Studies , 50 (6), 1100–1123.
  • Friedland, R. , & Alford, D. (1991). Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices, and institutional contradiction. In W. W. Powell & P. M. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 232–263). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Glynn, M. A. , & Navis, C. (2013). Categories, identities, and cultural classification: Moving beyond a model of categorical constraint. Journal of Management Studies , 50 , 1124–1137.
  • Greenwood, R. , Díaz, A. M. , Li, S. X. , & Lorente, J. C. (2010). The multiplicity of institutional logics and the heterogeneity of organizational responses. Organization Science , 21 (2), 521–539.
  • Greenwood, R. , Oliver, C. , Lawrence, T. , & Meyer, R. (Eds.). (2017). The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism (2nd ed.). London: SAGE.
  • Hardy, C. , & Maguire, S. (2017). Institutional entrepreneurship. In R. Greenwood , C. Oliver , T. Lawrence , & R. Meyer (Eds.), Handbook of organizational institutionalism (2nd ed., pp. 261–280). London: SAGE.
  • Kraatz, M. , & Block, E. (2008). Organizational implications of institutional pluralism. In R. Greenwood , C. Oliver , K. Sahlin , & R. Suddaby (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism (pp. 243–275). London: SAGE.
  • Lawrence, T. B. , & Suddaby, R. (2006). Institutions and institutional work. In S. Clegg , C. Hardy , T. Lawrence , & W. Nord (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational studies (pp. 215–254). London: SAGE.
  • Meyer, J. W. , & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology , 83 , 340–363.
  • Powell, W. W. , & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.). (1991). The new institutionalism in organizational analysis . Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations . Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
  • Tolbert, P. S. , David, R. J. , & Sine, W. D. (2011). Studying choice and change: The intersection of institutional theory and entrepreneurship research. Organization Science , 22 (5), 1332–1344.
  • Tolbert, P. S. , & Zucker, L.G. (1996). The institutionalization of institutional theory. In S. R. Clegg , C. Hard , & W. R. Nord (Eds.), Handbook of organization studies (pp. 175–190). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
  • Abrahamson, E. (1996). Management fashion. Academy of Management Review , 21 , 254–285.
  • Ahmadjian, C. , & Robinson, P. (2001). Safety in numbers: Downsizing and the deinstitutionalization of permanent employment in Japan. Administrative Science Quarterly , 46 , 622–654.
  • Ailon-Souday, G. , & Kunda, G. (2003). The local selves of global workers: The social construction of national identity in the face of organizational globalization. Organization Studies , 24 , 1073–1096.
  • Aldrich, H. E. , & Fiol, C. M. (1994). Fools rush in? The institutional context of industry creation. Academy of Management Review , 19 , 645–670.
  • Amburgey, T. L. , Dacin, T. , & Kelly, D. (1994). Disruptive selection and population segmentation: Interpopulation competition as a segregating process. Evolutionary Dynamics of Organizations , 240 , 254.
  • Barnard, C. I. (1938). Functions of the executive . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Baron, J. N. , Dobbin, F. R. , & Jennings P. D. (1986). War and peace: The evolution of modern personnel administration in U.S. industry. American Journal of Sociology , 92 , 350–383.
  • Battilana, J. , & Dorado, S. (2010). Building sustainable hybrid organizations: The case of commercial microfinance organizations. Academy of Management Journal , 53 , 1419–1440.
  • Battilana, J. , & Lee, M. (2014). Advancing research on hybrid organizing: Insights from the study of social enterprises. Academy of Management Annals , 8 , 397–441.
  • Battilana, J. , Sengul, M. , Pache, A.-C. , & Model, J. (2015). Harnessing productive tensions in hybrid organizations: The case of work integration social enterprises. Academy of Management Journal , 58 , 1658–1685.
  • Baum, J. A. C. , & Oliver, C. (1991). Institutional linkages and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly , 36 , 187–218.
  • Baum, J. A. C. , & Oliver, C. (1992). Institutional embeddedness and the dynamics of organizational populations. American Sociological Review , 57 , 540–559.
  • Berger, P. L. , & Luckmann, T. (1967). The social construction of reality . New York, NY: Doubleday.
  • Besharov, M. L. (2014). The relational ecology of identification: How organizational identification emerges when individuals hold divergent values. Academy of Management Journal , 57 , 1485–1512.
  • Besharov, M. L. , & Smith, W. K. (2014). Multiple institutional logics in organizations: Explaining their varied nature and implications. Academy of Management Review , 39 , 364–381.
  • Bitektine, A. (2011). Toward a theory of social judgments of organizations: The case of legitimacy, reputation, and status. Academy of Management Review , 36 , 151–179.
  • Callahan, R. E. (1962). Education and the cult of efficiency: A study of the social forces that have shaped the administration of the public schools . Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Canales, R. (2016). From ideals to institutions: Institutional entrepreneurship and the growth of Mexican small business finance. Organization Science , 27 , 1548–1573
  • Chuang, Y.-T. , Church, R. , & Ophir, R. (2011). Taking sides: The interactive influences of institutional mechanisms on the adoption of same-sex partner health benefits by Fortune 500 corporations, 1990–2003. Organization Science , 22 , 190–209.
  • Cooper, D. J. , Greenwood, R. , Hinings, B. , & Brown, J. L. (1998). Globalization and nationalism in a multinational accounting firm: The case of opening new markets in Eastern Europe. Accounting, Organizations and Society , 23 , 531.
  • Cyert, R. , & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm . Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
  • Dahrendorf, R. (1968). Essays in the theory of society . Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
  • Dalpiaz, E. , Rindova, V. , & Ravasi, D. (2016). Combining logics to transform organizational agency: Blending industry and art at Alessi. Administrative Science Quarterly , 61 , 347–392.
  • David, R. J. (2012). Institutional change and the growth of strategy consulting in the United States. In M. Kipping & T. Clark (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of management consulting (pp. 71–92). Oxford University Press.
  • David, R. J. , Sine, W. D. , & Haveman, H. A. (2013). Seizing opportunity in emerging fields: How institutional entrepreneurs legitimated the professional form of management consulting. Organization Science , 24 , 356–377.
  • David, R. J. , & Strang, D. (2006). When fashion is fleeting: Transitory collective beliefs and the dynamics of TQM consulting. Academy of Management Journal , 49 , 215–233.
  • DeSoucey, M. (2010). Gastronationalism: Food traditions and authenticity politics in the European Union. American Sociological Review , 75 , 432–455.
  • DiMaggio, P. J. (1988). Interest and agency in institutional theory. In L. G. Zucker (Ed.), Institutional patterns and organizations (pp. 3–22). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
  • DiMaggio, P. J. , & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review , 48 , 147–160.
  • Dobbin, F. , & Dowd, T. J. (1997). How policy shapes competition: Early railroad foundings in Massachusetts. Administrative Science Quarterly , 42 , 501–529.
  • Dobbin, F. , & Dowd, T. J. (2000). The market that antitrust built: Public policy, private coercion, and railroad acquisitions, 1825 to 1922. American Sociological Review , 65 , 631–657.
  • Dobbin, F. , & Sutton, J. R. (1998). The strength of a weak state: The rights revolution and the rise of human resources management divisions. American Journal of Sociology , 104 , 441–476.
  • Donaldson, L. (2001). The contingency theory of organizations . Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
  • Dowell, G. , & David, R. J. (2011). Effects of ancestral populations on entrepreneurial founding and failure: Private liquor stores in Alberta, 1994–2003. Industrial and Corporate Change , 20 (3), 825–853
  • Dunn, M. B. , & Jones, C. (2010). Institutional logics and institutional pluralism: The contestation of care and science logics in medical education, 1967–2005. Administrative Science Quarterly , 55 , 114–149.
  • Ebrahim, A. , Battilana, J. , & Mair, J. (2014). The governance of social enterprises: Mission drift and accountability challenges in hybrid organizations. Research in Organizational Behavior , 34 , 81–100.
  • Edman, J. , & Ahmadjian, C. L. (2017). Empty categories and industry emergence: The rise and fall of Japanese ji-biru. In M.-D. Seidel & H. Greve (Eds.), Emergence (Research in the sociology of organizations) (Vol. 50, pp. 109–140). Bingley, U.K.: Emerald Group.
  • Fligstein, N. M. (1990). The transformation of corporate control . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
  • Fligstein, N. M. (1996). Markets as politics: A political-cultural approach to market institutions. American Sociological Review , 61 , 656–673.
  • Garfinkel, H. (1967). Studies in Ethnomethodology . Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
  • Garud, R. (2008). Conferences as Venues for the Configuration of Emerging Organizational Fields: The Case of Cochlear Implants. Journal of Management Studies , 45 , 1061–1088.
  • Glynn, M. A. , & Navis, C. (2010). Entrepreneurship, institutional emergence, and organizational leadership: Tuning in to “the next big thing” in satellite radio. In W. D. Sine & R. J. David (Eds.), Institutions and entrepreneurship: Research in the sociology of work (Vol. 21, pp. 257–286). Bingley, U.K.: Emerald Group.
  • Greenwood, R. , Oliver, C. , Sahlin, K. , & Suddaby, R. (Eds.). (2008). The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism . London: SAGE.
  • Greenwood, R. , Oliver, C. , Sahlin, K. , & Suddaby, R. (2008). Introduction. In R. Greenwood , C. Oliver , K. Sahlin , & R. Suddaby (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism (pp. 1–46). London: SAGE.
  • Greenwood, R. , Raynard, M. , Kodeih, F. , Micelotta, E. R. , & Lounsbury, M. (2011). Institutional complexity and organizational responses. Academy of Management Annals , 5 (1), 317–371.
  • Greenwood, R. , Suddaby, R. , & Hinings, C. (2002). Theorizing change: The role of professional associations in the transformation of institutionalized fields. Academy of Management Journal , 45 (1), 58–80.
  • Hargadon, A. B. , & Douglas, Y. (2001). When innovations meet institutions: Edison and the design of the electric light. Administrative Science Quarterly , 46 , 476–501.
  • Haveman, H. A. (1993). Follow the leader: Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new markets. Administrative Science Quarterly , 38 , 593–627.
  • Haveman, H. A. , Russo, M. V. , & Meyer, A. D. (2001). Organizational environments in flux: The impact of regulatory punctuations on organizational domains, CEO succession, and performance. Organization Science , 12 , 253–273.
  • Hiatt, S. R. , Sine, W. D. , & Tolbert, P. S. (2009). From Pabst to Pepsi: The deinstitutionalization of social practices and the creation of entrepreneurial opportunities. Administrative Science Quarterly , 54 (4), 635–667.
  • Jay, J. (2012). Navigating paradox as a mechanism of change and innovation in hybrid organizations. Academy of Management Journal , 56 , 137–159.
  • Jones, C. , Maoret, M. , Massa, F. G. , & Svejenova, S. (2012). Rebels with a cause: Formation, contestation, and expansion of the de novo category “modern architecture,” 1870–1975. Organization Science , 23 (6), 1523–1545.
  • Kelly, E. (2003). The strange history of employer sponsored child care: Interested actors, uncertainty, and the transformation of law in organizational fields. American Journal of Sociology , 109 , 606–649.
  • Kennedy, M. T. (2008). Getting counted: Markets, media, and reality. American Sociological Review , 73 , 270–295.
  • Khaire, M. (2014). Fashioning an industry: Socio-cognitive processes in the construction of worth of a new industry. Organization Studies , 35 , 41–74.
  • Khaire, M. , & Wadhwani, R. D. (2010). Changing landscapes: The construction of meaning and value in a new market category—Modern Indian Art. Academy of Management Journal , 53 (6), 1281–1304.
  • Kraatz, M. , & Flores, R. (2015). Reinfusing values. In M. S. Kraatz (Ed.), Institutions and ideals: Philip Selznick’s legacy for organizational studies (Research in the sociology of organizations) (Vol. 44, pp. 353–381). Bingley, U.K.: Emerald Group.
  • Lawrence, P. R. , & Lorsch, J. W. (1967). Differentiation and integration in complex organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly , 12 , 1–47.
  • Lounsbury, M. (2007). A tale of two cities: Competing logics and practice variation in the professionalizing of mutual funds. Academy of Management Journal , 50 , 289–307.
  • Lounsbury, M. , Ventresca, M. , & Hirsch, P. (2003). Social movements, field frames and industry emergence: A cultural-political perspective on U.S. recycling. Socio-Economic Review , 1 (1), 71–104.
  • Maguire, S. , Hardy, C. , & Lawrence, T. (2004). Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in Canada. Academy of Management Journal , 47 (5), 657–679.
  • Mair, J. , Mayer, J. , & Lutz, E. (2015). Navigating institutional plurality: Organizational governance in hybrid organizations. Organization Studies , 36 , 713–739.
  • March, J. G. , & Simon, H. (1958). Organizations . New York, NY: Wiley.
  • Mellahi, K. , Frynas, J. G. , Sun, P. , & Siegel, D. (2016). A review of the nonmarket strategy literature: Toward a multi-theoretical integration. Journal of Management , 42 (1), 143–173.
  • Meyer, M. W. , & Zucker, L. G. (1989). Permanently failing organizations . Newbury Park, CA: SAGE.
  • Mezias, S. J. , & Boyle, E. (2005). Blind trust: Market control, legal environments, and the dynamics of competitive intensity in the early American film industry, 1893–1920. Administrative Science Quarterly , 50 , 1–34.
  • Navis, C. , & Glynn, M. (2010). How new market categories emerge: Temporal dynamics of legitimacy, identity, and entrepreneurship in satellite radio, 1990–2005. Administrative Science Quarterly , 55 , 439–471.
  • Navis, C. , & Glynn, M. A. (2011). Legitimate distinctiveness and the entrepreneurial identity: Influence on investor judgments of new venture plausibility. Academy of Management Review , 36 , 479–499.
  • Newman, J. I. , & Giardina, M. D. (2010). Neoliberalism’s last lap? NASCAR nation and the cultural politics of sport. American Behavioral Scientist , 53 , 1511–1529.
  • Okhmatovskiy, I. , & David, R. J. (2012). Setting your own standards: Internal corporate governance codes as a response to institutional pressure. Organization Science , 23 (1), 155–176.
  • Oliver, C. (1991). Strategic responses to institutional processes. Academy of Management Review , 16 , 145–179.
  • Oliver, C. (1992). The antecedents of deinstitutionalization. Organization Studies , 13 , 563–588.
  • Pache, A. , & Santos, F. (2013). Inside the hybrid organization: Selective coupling as a response to competing institutional logics. Academy of Management Journal , 56 , 972–1001.
  • Parsons, T. (1956). Suggestions for a sociological approach to the theory of organizations—I. Administrative Science Quarterly , 1 , 63–85.
  • Parsons, T. (1960). Some ingredients of a formal theory of organization. In T. Parsons (Ed.), Structure and process in modern society (pp. 56–97). Glencoe, IL: Free Press.
  • Perrow, C. M. (1972). Complex organizations: A critical essay . Glenview, IL: Scott Foreman.
  • Peterson, R. A. (1997). Creating country music: Fabricating authenticity . Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Pontikes, E. , & Kim, R. (2017). Strategic Categorization. In R. Durand , N. Granqvist , & A. Tyllstrom (Eds.), From Categories to Categorization: Studies in Sociology, Organizations and Strategy at the Crossroads (Vol. 51, pp. 71–111). Bingley, U.K.: Emerald Publishing Limited.
  • Purdy, J. M. , & Gray, B. (2009). Conflicting logics, mechanisms of diffusion, and multilevel dynamics in emerging institutional fields. Academy of Management Journal , 52 (2), 355–380.
  • Ramus, T. , Vaccaro, A. , & Brusoni, S. (2017). Institutional complexity in turbulent times: Formalization, collaboration, and the emergence of blended logics. Academy of Management Journal , 60 (4), 1253–1284.
  • Rao, H. , Monin, P. , & Durand, R. (2003). Institutional change in Toque Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an identity movement in French gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology , 108 (4), 795–843.
  • Reay, T. , & Hinings, C. R. (2009). Managing the rivalry of competing institutional logics. Organization Studies , 30 (6), 629–652.
  • Riad, S. , & Vaara, E. (2011). Varieties of national metonymy in media accounts of international mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Management Studies , 48 , 737–771.
  • Schoonhoven, C. B. (1981). Problems with contingency theory: Testing assumptions hidden within. Administrative Science Quarterly , 26 , 349–377.
  • Scott, W. R. (1975). Organizational structure. Annual Review of Sociology , 1 , 1–20.
  • Seo, M.-G. , & Creed, W. E. D. (2002). Institutional contradictions, praxis, and institutional change: A dialectical perspective. Academy of Management Review , 27 , 222–247.
  • Selznick, P. (1949). The TVA and the grass roots . Berkeley: University of California Press.
  • Selznick, P. (1957). Leadership in administration . New York, NY: Harper and Row.
  • Simon, H. (1947). Administrative behavior . New York, NY: Free Press.
  • Sine, W. D. , & David, R. J. (2003). Environmental jolts, institutional change, and the creation of entrepreneurial opportunity in the US electric power industry. Research Policy , 32 , 185–207.
  • Sine, W. D. , David, R. J. , & Mitsuhashi, H. (2007). From plan to plant: Effects of certification on operational start-up in the emergent independent power sector. Organization Science , 18 , 578.
  • Sine, W. D. , Haveman, H. A. , & Tolbert, P. S. (2005). Risky business? Entrepreneurship in the new independent-power sector. Administrative Science Quarterly , 50 , 200–232.
  • Sine, W. D. , & Lee, B. H. (2009). Tilting at windmills? The environmental movement and the emergence of the U.S. wind energy sector. Administrative Science Quarterly , 54 (1), 123–155.
  • Smets, M. , Jarzabkowski, P. , Burke, G. , & Spee, P. (2015). Reinsurance trading in Lloyd’s of London: Balancing conflicting yet complementary logics in practice. Academy of Management Journal , 58 , 932–970.
  • Smith, W. K. , & Besharov, M. L. (2019). Bowing before dual gods: How structured flexibility sustains organizational hybridity. Administrative Science Quarterly , 64 , 1–44.
  • Strang, D. , & Meyer, J. (1993). Institutional conditions for diffusion. Theory and Society , 22 (4), 487–511.
  • Swaminathan, A. (1995). The proliferation of specialist organizations in the American wine industry, 1941–1990. Administrative Science Quarterly , 40 (4), 653–680.
  • Swaminathan, A. , & Wade, J. B. (2001). Social movement theory and the evolution of new organizational forms. In C. Schoonhoven & E. Romanelli (Eds.), The entrepreneurship dynamic (pp. 286–313). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
  • Thornton, P. , & Ocasio, W. (1999). Institutional logics and the historical contingency of power in organizations: Executive succession in the higher education publishing industry, 1958–1990. American Journal of Sociology , 105 , 801.
  • Tienari, J. , Vaara, E. , & Björkman, I. (2003). Global capitalism meets national spirit: Discourses in media texts on a cross-border acquisition. Journal of Management Inquiry , 12 , 377–393.
  • Tolbert, P. S. , & Zucker, L. G. (1983). Institutional sources of change in the formal structure of organizations: The diffusion of civil service reform, 1880–1935. Administrative Science Quarterly , 28 , 22–39.
  • Tolbert, P. S. , & Zucker, L. G. (1996). The institutionalization of institutional theory. In S. R. Clegg , C. Hard , & W. R. Nord (Eds.), Handbook of organization studies (pp. 175–190). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.
  • Vaara, E. , & Tienari, J. (2002). Justification, legitimization and naturalization of mergers and acquisitions: A critical discourse analysis of media texts. Organization , 9 , 275–304.
  • Vaara, E. , & Tienari, J. (2011). On the narrative construction of multinational corporations: An antenarrative analysis of legitimation and resistance in a cross-border merger. Organization Science , 22 , 370–390.
  • Weber, K. , Heinze, K. L. , & DeSoucey, M. (2008). Forage for thought: Mobilizing codes in the movement for grass-fed meat and dairy products. Administrative Science Quarterly , 53 (3), 529–567.
  • Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology ( G. Roth & C. Wittich , Eds.; E. Fischoff et al., Trans.; 2 vols.). Berkeley: University of California Press. Original work published 1921–1922.
  • Weick, K. (1969). Social psychology of organizations . Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
  • Wry, T. , Lounsbury, M. , & Glynn, M. A. (2011). Legitimating new categories of organizations: Stories as distributed cultural entrepreneurship. Organization Science , 22 (2), 339–463.
  • Zilber, T. (2002). Institutionalization as an interplay between actors, meanings and actions: The case of a rape crisis center in Israel. Academy of Management Journal , 45 , 234–252.
  • Zorn, D. M. (2004). Here a chief, there a chief: The rise of the CFO in the American firm. American Sociological Review , 69 , 345–364.
  • Zucker, L. G. (1977). The role of institutionalization in cultural persistence. American Sociological Review , 42 , 726–743.
  • Zucker, L. G. (1983). Organizations as institutions. Research in the Sociology of Organizations , 2 , 1–47.
  • Zucker, L. G. (1988). Institutional patterns and organizations: Culture and environment . Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

1. The label “institutional theory” is used here while recognizing that the large body of research under this label shares an orienting perspective rather than a formal set of causal propositions, per most definitions of “theory.” Further, the label is used to denote only research within organization studies, and thus does not include institutional research in the fields of economics, political science, or law (for a discussion of how these relate to institutional theory in organization studies, see Scott [ 1995 ]).

2. Institutional entrepreneurship is frequently used synonymously with “institutional work,” a construct originally proposed by Lawrence and Suddaby ( 2006 ). Like institutional entrepreneurship, institutional work has come to be used in practice to describe all agentic activities directed towards creating, maintaining, or changing institutions.

3. The first use of this term is often credited to Callahan ( 1962 ).

Related Articles

  • Agency Theory in Business and Management Research
  • Business Groups as an Organizational Model

Printed from Oxford Research Encyclopedias, Business and Management. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a single article for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 10 August 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [185.80.149.115]
  • 185.80.149.115

Character limit 500 /500

  • Social Science
  • Institutional Theory

The Diffusion and Use of Institutional Theory: A Cross-Disciplinary Longitudinal Literature Survey

  • September 2009
  • Journal of Information Technology 24(4):354-368
  • 24(4):354-368

Vishanth Weerakkody at University of Bradford

  • University of Bradford

Yogesh Kumar Dwivedi at Swansea University

  • Swansea University

Zahir Irani at University of Bradford

Abstract and Figures

Diffusion and use of institutional theory according to year of publication

Discover the world's research

  • 25+ million members
  • 160+ million publication pages
  • 2.3+ billion citations
  • INFORM TECHNOL MANAG
  • Saeed Tajdini
  • INFORM SYST FRONT

Rohit Madan

  • Nguyễn Phước Hoàng
  • Nguyễn Thị Mộng Thu
  • Erik Elgersma
  • Beverly Wagner

Natalie McDougall

  • Int J Account Inform Syst

Giovana Schiavi

  • Inform Tech People

Joshua Ofoeda

  • TECHNOL FORECAST SOC

Lapo Mola

  • Nathalie Richebé

Andrea Carugati

  • L. E. Davis
  • Douglass C. North
  • S. G. Checkland
  • D. C. North
  • Geoffrey McNicoll

Lynne Zucker

  • Paul DiMaggio

Brian Rowan

  • John W. Meyer

Adriaan Schout

  • Douglas C. North

R. Edward Freeman

  • Oliver Williamson
  • Recruit researchers
  • Join for free
  • Login Email Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google Welcome back! Please log in. Email · Hint Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google No account? Sign up

Advertisement

Advertisement

Systematic review of institutional innovation literature: towards a multi-level management model

  • Published: 02 February 2022
  • Volume 73 , pages 731–785, ( 2023 )

Cite this article

institutional theory literature review

  • Hameeda A. AlMalki 1 &
  • Christopher M. Durugbo 1  

12k Accesses

16 Citations

Explore all metrics

Institutional innovation creates smart institutions that idiosyncratically thrive in a world of exponential change. Through policy-driven interventions and experiential learning, managers of institutions become adept at delivering praxis- and crisis-driven innovations required for survival and success. Similarly, the management of institutional innovation remains an interest in research due to links of this form of innovation to economic growth, and the demands of on-going major socioeconomic transformations due to technological advances, increased occurrences of major crises, and emerging socioeconomic challenges. Accordingly, a key question arising from the literature concerns the range of determinants and priorities that influence institutional innovation for delivering society value. Thus, the onus is on scholarship to capture and advance knowledge for harnessing the potency of institutional innovation. The purpose of this article is to analyse the current state of research on institutional innovation. Using the systematic review methodology, we identify and critically appraise 485 peer-reviewed scientific publications between 1969 and 2021. The review finds key determinants and management priorities with a view to developing a multi-level management model of institutional innovation. Guided by insights from the review, the article sets a research agenda for future management studies of institutional innovation.

Similar content being viewed by others

institutional theory literature review

Open Innovation and Governance Models in Public Sector: A Systematic Literature Review

institutional theory literature review

Regional innovation system research trends: toward knowledge management and entrepreneurial ecosystems

institutional theory literature review

Assessing the Origins, Evolution and Prospects of National Innovation Systems

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

1 Introduction

For institutions like governments and businesses, pressures to stay abreast with social changes and scientific advances in society, serve as the impetus for innovation, Footnote 1 i.e., institutional innovation, which changes not only global competition but also the basis of competition itself within, and between institutions. Existing viewpoints on institutional innovation expand management strategy and policy horizons for institutions to include processes such as supply chain management, product innovation, and customer relationship management. These viewpoints redefine roles and relationships across independent entities to accelerate and amplify learning and to reduce risks (Hagel and Brown 2013 ; Fuentelsaz et al. 2018 ; Gretchenko et al. 2018 ). The institutional innovation perspective also depends on mechanisms for building scalable, long-term trust-based relationships through learning capabilities (Hao and Yunlong 2014 ; Chittoor et al. 2015 ; Phornlaphatrachakorn 2019 ) and increasing awareness of environmental pressures (Chu et al. 2018 ; Tang et al. 2020a ). Consequently, institutional innovation underpins the government, educational, training, and corporate policies that solve complex social problems, particularly through systematic collaborations between government agencies, universities, industries, and users.

In the management literature, the main problem for institutional innovation research remains questions on the legitimacy of institutions (Tingey and Webb 2020 ) and the necessary characteristics of novel initiatives that address socio-economic challenges such as income inequality (Biurrun 2020 ). Fittingly, there is on-going and increasing theoretical and empirical interest in the determinants of innovation (Molina-Morales and Mas-Verdu 2008 ; Li et al. 2020 ). For this line of inquiry, an important focus is on a working hypothesis that conformance to institutional frameworks underpinned by innovation has the potential to deliver societal value (Ventura et al. 2020 ; Chebrolu and Dutta 2021 ). Such frameworks highlight the dynamic nature of institutional environments, context-specific nature of innovations, and proactivity of innovators within institutions. Another area of interest (e.g. Pfister et al. ( 2021 ) and Tang et al. ( 2020b )), lies in understanding the priorities of institutions for managing the increasingly sophisticated policy toolbox used by governments to facilitate institutional innovation for public sector composition, creation of tax credits, investment in indigenous talent, intellectual property strategies, environmental protection regulations, funding for research and enterprise, etc. Here, the emphasis is on the nature of deep innovation and reviews of institutional structures needed to sustain livelihoods during times of historic change (Beunen and Kole 2021 ; Gongbuzeren et al. 2021 ; Hughes et al. 2021 ). In view of these on-going interests, there is a need to review and capture the current state of research on institutional innovation regularly for advancing domain knowledge and highlighting paths for future research.

The aim of this article is to review existing literature on institutional innovation based on a systematic approach. The review examines the trends of research methodologies and theories in studies, analyses key determinants, and synthesises management priorities for institutional innovation. Using knowledge captured from the review process, the article proposes a multi-level management model and sets a research agenda that challenges management researchers to advance the field of institutional innovation.

For this review, the interest lies in enriching the on-going work by researchers, managers, and policymakers to analyse the main determinants and priorities of institutional innovation. Such analysis remains critical for two reasons. First , innovation management studies that link institutional factors to economic growth contribute to a well-established domain of management research. This domain remains the focus of current studies (Jiang and Zhang 2020 ; Edwards and King 2021 ) to underscore the role of new ventures, market creation, inclusivity, and assistance afforded by institutions for the growth of economies and technological trajectory. Here, innovative activities within institutions act a central force to economic growth because they determine sharing rules within society and complement other growth explanations such as frugality, resilience, geography, trade, and capital (Gande et al. 2020 ; Tomizawa et al. 2020 ; Nkundabanyanga et al. 2020 ). Second , the world is at the brink of a major socioeconomic transformation due to the effects of technological revolutions like Industry 4.0, increased occurrences of major crises (e.g., natural disasters, health emergences, regional conflicts, terrorism, and economic recessions), and emerging challenges associated with climate change, rise of populism and geo-political tensions, environmental biodegradation, and rising inequality. Coping with this transformation remains complex and challenging. With thin mind, this review intends to contribute to management research and discourse on institutional innovation based on the rationale that a multi-level management model of institutional innovation could deepen and enhance understanding of determinants and priorities for supporting economic growth and confronting emerging challenges of major socioeconomic transformations. This review confronts the following research question:

What are the main determinants and management priorities of institutional innovation in the literature?

The remainder of this review proceeds as follows. The next section gives an overview of institutional innovation, followed by the review methodology and findings on key determinant and management priorities, respectively. The review then presents the multi-level management model followed by a discussion of potential future questions and challenges for management research on institutional innovation.

2 Institutional innovation: an overview

Institutions are social constructs defined as “the rules of a society or of organisations that facilitate coordination among people by helping them form expectations which each person can reasonably hold in dealing with others” (Ruttan and Hayami 1984 , p. 204). These rules govern behaviour, produce more long-standing facets of human systems, and steer societies along specific development paths (McCann 2004 ; Woodhill 2010 ) but depend on the will and creativity of individuals (Shaffer 1969 ). Through formal (e.g. laws) and informal (e.g. social norms) mechanisms, institutions concomitantly emerge from and determine socio-economic exchanges (North 1991 ; Scott 2006 ) within public and private spheres of human endeavour. In this context, some researchers argue that ‘institutional void’, i.e. the absence of formal institutional mechanisms, triggers the use of informal institutional mechanisms for guiding and supporting interactions (Raghubanshi et al. 2021 ). An alternate view argues that the emergence of institutions stems from constant-cause (same factors) and path-dependence (different factors) explanations (Parrado 2008 ). Recognising that institutions are ‘rules of the game’ (North 1990 ; Edquist 2006 ; Scott 2006 ), recent studies (e.g. Chebrolu and Dutta ( 2021 ) and Hughes et al. ( 2021 )) argue that radical perturbations, such as the Coronavirus Disease 2019 (COVID-19) pandemic, are ‘game changers’ that cause socio-economic distress and disrupt the status quo. Yet, these perturbations also pose opportunities for innovation to reimagine existing institutions and to transform the supportive ecosystems of such institutions.

According to Hagel and Brown ( 2013 , p. 4), institutional innovation is a shift from scalable efficiency to scalable learning, such that organisations “can become more adept at generating richer innovations at other levels, including products, services, business models, and management systems”. Similarly, Raffaelli and Glynn ( 2015 , p. 409) define institutional innovation as “novel, useful, and legitimate change that disrupts, to varying degrees, the cognitive, normative, or regulative mainstays of an organisational field”. For Li et al. (2020b; p.115801), institutional innovation is “the creation of a new and more effective system to encourage people’s behaviour, and the realisation of social sustainable development and innovation under the existing production and living environment”. This form of innovation emerges from injections of investments and initiatives reinforced by policies and strategies as posited by the ‘institutional-pump’ model (Durugbo et al. 2020a ), which contrasts with technology-push and market-pull theories on innovation (Martin 1994 ), as summarised by Fig.  1 . For instance, ‘pumps’ of investment underscore directed actions that implement institutional changes proposed via contracts, internalisation, regulation, and referendums (Polopolus 1969 ; Hug 2005 ).

figure 1

Comparing the institutional-pump model to technology-push and market-pull theories of innovation (Durugbo et al. 2020a )

Using systems thinking, Johannessen ( 2008 ) attempts to explain changes due to institutional innovation along pattern, functional, historical, and cybernetic forms of causal processes. The author suggests these different processes account for legitimacy taken for granted (cognitive) or engrained in social pressures from institutional actors (normative). Similarly, Woodhill ( 2010 ) applies a systems complexity standpoint to argue for institutional innovation capacity that involves navigating complexity; learning collaboratively; engaging politically; and being self-reflective. Irrespective of the characterisation, institutional innovation as a concept has some lawful implications for organisational actors. Like other innovations, institutional innovation concerns novelty and utility, but differs in that it is also “legitimate, credible and appropriate” (Raffaelli and Glynn 2015 , p. 407). Institutional innovation rose to prominence due to development in sectors such as healthcare and manufacturing, with research on the subject gaining traction in the mid-1970s. Major management changes spurred by research undertaken in England and Wales in 1963 and 1973 as well as in France and North America account for most of this growing interest (Sewell et al. 2005 ). Here, insights provided from studies over the years underscore how institutions stimulate innovation to reduce uncertainties, coordinate the use of knowledge, mediate conflicts, and provide incentives.

Literature offers three main viewpoints on institutional innovation, as compared by Table 1 . The first viewpoint, induced institutional innovation (Ruttan and Hayami 1984 ; Ruttan 1989 , 2006 ), posits that resource imbalances due to institutional constraints motivates a dialectic interaction between demand for and supply of innovation. This interaction also considers the influence of technological and cultural changes in society. Here, innovators harness potential opportunities associated with overcoming institutional disequilibrium due to changes in market sizes, government rules, etc. (Grabowski 1991 ; Godden 1991 ; Ruttan 2006 ). The next viewpoint, continuous institutional innovation, notes the rapid advances and waves in technological breakthroughs (Li et al. 2020 ; Xie and Yang 2021 ) that improve democratic governance (Biggs 2008 ; Fung 2012 ). These breakthroughs emerge from and deliver provisioning in four main forms: (i) technological infrastructure that enact innovative policies; (ii) high technology that engineer complex solutions; (iii) computer-based information systems that enable innovative business processes; and (iv) digital technologies that enhance service delivery (Durugbo et al. 2020a ). The third viewpoint, collective institutional innovation (Hargrave and Van De Ven 2006 ), uses social movement and technology innovation literature to argue for a model of collective action for change that is field-dependent and occurs according to the exchanges between actors within the field. The viewpoint also highlights four perspectives on institutional innovation involving adaption, diffusion, design, and collection action—according to varying actor level foci and reproduction/ construction modes of change.

Institutional innovation is important for accelerating economic activities and contributes to added economic value. This is because this form of innovation shapes the behaviour of organisations (Edquist 2006 ) and motivates institutional actors to plan modifications that spur a variety of collective activities carefully (Schickler 2001 ; Veiga et al. 2020 ). Institutions also favour innovation because the process gives rise to stability necessary for fluid knowledge exchanges and learning processes (Carlsson 1997 ). In discussions concerning the role of innovation for economic growth, recent research accentuates the need to explore selective forms of interventions that support internationalisation in spheres of education (Foray and Woerter 2021 ; Fumasoli and Rossi 2021 ), the public sector (Buchheim et al. 2020 ), and business (Hernández et al. 2021 ). Some key areas of interest for interventions include fostering innovative work behaviour (AlEssa and Durugbo 2021 ), and reducing barriers (Hueske and Guenther 2015 ). Using transformative policies, pro-innovation institutions also attempt to address inequality in economic systems (Biurrun 2020 ; Perry 2021 ), manage immigrant integration that boosts cultural diversity (Nyseth and Ventura López 2021 ), and confront the conflating challenges of energy development and environmental protection (Gao et al. 2020 ). Yet, institutional innovation is difficult and faces unease, disagreement, and conflict due to the dynamic nature and tension between institutional persistence and innovative change (Hargadon and Douglas 2001 ). Evidence also suggests that the application of innovation generates additional risks for some institutions (e.g. financial institutions) due to the peculiar complex nature of delivered services (Mishchenko et al. 2021 ). Furthermore, there are arguments that institutional innovation negatively creates “certain structural and distributional biases” against the backdrop of economic value for institutional actors and participants (Farrell and Runge 1983 ). Such biases threaten the legitimacy and question the efficacy of the innovation by institutions.

Although, related reviews adopt the systematic approach to review institutional change research (van der Heijden and Kuhlmann 2017 ; Bakir and Gunduz 2017 ), the work presented in this article is unique in its focus on institutional innovation. Motivated by the need to deepen knowledge on institutional innovation determinants and priorities, the review presented in this article, seeks to enrich the discourse on factors and actions required for managing institutional innovation and revising existing institutional structures.

3 Methodology

Motivated by RQ , this article applies the systematic review methodology (Khan et al. 2003 ) to analyse research studies on institutional innovation. The process for this review, shown in Fig.  2 , consists of three main phases: planning, conducting, and reporting (Kitchenham and Charters 2007 ; Durugbo et al. 2020b ). Planning the review involves creating an initial protocol that concretises and formalises the review plan. Table 2 outlines the review protocol concerning the context for the research, the specific research questions, the planned search strategy, and the criteria for publication selection.

figure 2

Systematic literature review process (Kitchenham and Charters 2007 )

Conducting the review is the phase entailing the selection of studies, quality assessment to include studies, data extraction and monitoring, and the data synthesis. Selection concentrates on sources available on two online databases. First, Scopus ( https://www.scopus.com ), which is a scientific search engine with the most inclusive coverage of published peer-reviewed research. The database provides access to over 26,000 + scientific, technical, and medical (STM) journal titles from over 7000 + publishers. Second, Web of Science ( www.webofscience.com ), which is a citation database that tracks and provides access to over 171 million records with about 1.9 billion cited references. Using Scopus and Web of Science, the review identifies, screens, and accumulates sources related to institutional innovation. The search process for the review applies a range of search strings to identify and screen sources based on titles, keywords, and abstracts of articles. The specific strings that serve as the basis for this review are “institution AND innovation”, “innovation AND institution”, “institution innovation”, and “institutional innovation”. This search generated 1600 and 1515 results on Scopus and Web of Science respectively, and further refined searches limiting results to journal articles published in English produced 983 and 893 results on Scopus and Web of Science, respectively. Cross-referencing to identify duplicates and screening for relevance yielded 485 articles published between 1969 and 2021 that serve as the basis for this review. Figure  3 shows the yearly distribution of the review articles, indicating a growing trend and interest in the topic, particularly in the past 7 years. The review relies on empirical and theoretical peer reviewed journal articles as the main inclusion criteria. Consequently, this process excludes conference proceeding papers, doctoral dissertations, master’s theses, textbooks, and unpublished working papers.

figure 3

Yearly distribution of institutional innovation publications

For reporting the review , data analysis initially presents trends and classifications of studies. This phase derives data from preceding steps to inspect, clean, transform, and model review data on methodologies and theories within studies. Figure  4 a shows that the main methodologies used in the literature are case studies (171 articles), econometric models based on longitudinal panel data (111 articles), surveys based mainly on cross-sectional data (52 articles), and essays involving critiques, discussions, and historical analyses (50 articles). The review also contains studies using mixed methods (29 articles), literature reviews (24 articles), conceptual pieces (25 articles), decision analysis using techniques such as simulation and multi-criteria decision analysis (12), experimentation (5 articles), action research (4 articles), and meta-analysis (3 articles).

figure 4

Analysis of review data according to a methodologies and b management theories used in studies

The analysis also finds, as shown in Fig.  4 b, strong theoretical underpinnings for institutional innovation studies, with institutional theory, rather unsurprisingly, dominating coverage with use in 95 sources (82 usages in isolation and an additional 13 usages from the 28 studies with multiple theories). Some other theories used in the literature include systems of innovation, transaction cost, resource-based view, absorptive capacity, dynamic capabilities, regulatory focus, and social network theories, as presented by Table 3 . The reporting phase also involves a synthesis of the findings, consistent with the research protocol, and geared towards presenting the extracted data in a manner that is coherent with the review objective and intended outcomes (Kitchenham and Charters 2007 ). Synthesis during the review is descriptive and intended to present clusters and outlines of the key determinants and management priorities for institutional innovation. In establishing the determinants, the review creates categories of concepts that serve as the phenomena investigated. For management priorities, the review applies clustering to capture themes that underscore focal points for management and interventions to enhance institutional innovation. Applying conceptual and thematic analysis is consistent with the systematic review methodology (Khan et al. 2003 ; Durugbo 2020 ) and enables the review to present the findings in a form suitable for dissemination. The next section reports the findings of the synthesis of articles.

4 Main determinants of institutional innovation

Literature suggests institutional innovation management exists in four main contexts: organisational, environmental, social, and governmental. These innovation contexts strengthen the contribution of intangible resources (e.g., proximity, relational capital, cooperation, and learning) as sources of economic growth. Constructs such as the quadruple helix (Schütz et al. 2018 ), Footnote 2 posit on actors and systems for these contexts with institutions pursuing radical (Gao et al. 2015 ; Martínez-Pérez et al. 2019 ; Qing et al. 2019 ; Ventura et al. 2020 ), incremental (Vermeulen et al. 2007b ), and in some cases, frugal (Kunamaneni 2019 ; Ananthram and Chan 2021 ; Jayabalan et al. 2021 ) innovations.

Organisational innovation presents the core context for institutional innovation, harnessing the potentials of open and technological innovations, and delivering breakthrough processes and products in areas such as healthcare (Laurell 2018 ), finance (Boulanger and Gagnon 2018 ), and education (Sein-Echaluce et al. 2017 ; Boroujerdi et al. 2020 ; Thani et al. 2021 ). Delving into complexities of intra- and inter-organisational innovation underlines the significance of new ventures and enterprise (Fuentelsaz et al. 2018 ), innovativeness and innovative behaviour (Sun et al. 2017 ; Da Silva 2019 ), and innovative investment and funding (Huston et al. 2015 ) for sustaining economic growth of cities and communities. With increasing awareness of an emergent environmental crisis, institutions also pursue environmental (green and eco forms of) innovations aimed at sustainable development (Adomssent and Michelsen 2006 ; Wang et al. 2019a ). Eco-friendly energy sources (e.g., solar, hydro and wind) and practices (e.g. reverse logistics) afford institutions with opportunities for enhancing nature's resilience to environmental pressures and for promoting responsible and accountable use of natural resources (Huang and Yang 2014 ; Polzin et al. 2016 ; Chen et al. 2018 ). This context motivates studies of management strategies such as stringent environmental regulations (Chu et al. 2018 ; Yao et al. 2019 ), reverse logistics (Aguilera-Caracuel and Ortiz-de-Mandojana 2013 ; Huang and Yang 2014 ), brand equity (Yao et al. 2021 ), and mobilisation of private finance (Polzin et al. 2016 ). Additionally, institutions chase social innovations in efforts to address complex social problems such as income inequality, poverty alleviation, urban mobility, and persistent societal and endemic violent conflicts. The intent is to create societal value (Turker and Vural 2017 ) and promote social enterprise (Kolk and Lenfant 2015 ; Venugopal and Viswanathan 2019 ) in conflict-affected areas plagued by institutional gaps. Co-creating and legitimating social innovation (Onsongo 2019 ; Kumari et al. 2020 ) becomes paramount as institutions explore agents of social change for sectoral diffusion patterns (Peirce 1991 ; Windrum et al. 2018 ) along with empowerment in public welfare for marginalised citizens and local communities that creates opportunities for positive change (Andersen and Bilfeldt 2017 ). Governmental (regulatory or policy (Costa-Font and Puig-Junoy 2007 )) innovation involves initiatives by governments that seek to confront discrepancies between the existing and attainable quality of life for citizens (Shaffer 1969 ). These discrepancies stem from issues surrounding employability, inequality in advanced economies, over-concentration of wealth for few at the top of the income distribution (Biurrun 2020 ; Fumasoli and Rossi 2021 ). Examples of policy innovations include the New Deal legislation of the 1930s that generated economic value in the form of reduced risk and increased rewards for farmers (Farrell and Runge 1983 ) and the Federal Reserve Act of 1913 for supporting bankers (Ferderer 2003 ). Intergovernmental bodies also implement policy innovation, e.g., the Birds and Habitats Directives that targets the sustainable conservation of natural habitats and species (Beunen and Kole 2021 ). Traditionally the mode for socioeconomic advances by contemporary societies (Rickards et al. 1996 ; Tingey and Webb 2020 ), recent studies highlight the increasing use of innovative policy toolboxes by local, national, and regional governments of emerging economies (May 2008 ; Helleiner and Wang 2018 ; Tang et al. 2020b ) for boosting collaboration (Gachie 2020 ) and effectiveness (Rodríguez-Pose and Zhang 2020 ).

In view of these contexts, this analysis of the literature identifies four categories of determinants for institutional innovation: (i) institutional quality and control, (ii) institutional diversity and reputation, (iii) institutional value and output, and (iv) institutional reform and improvement. Table 4 summarises these key determinants, and the next subsections outline the main concepts within the categories.

4.1 Institutional quality and control

Topically, the most investigated category of determinants and independent variables is institutional quality and control that influences efficiency and dexterity of innovation inputs. Studies focus on institutional quality because empirical evidence suggests this concept influences the ability of firms to acquire advanced technologies (Wu et al. 2016 ; Kawabata and Camargo Junior 2020 ) along with the probability, capacity, and intensity of innovation (Rodríguez-Pose and Zhang 2020 ; Mosconi and D’Ingiullo 2021 ). Total quality management (TQM) offers a critical paradigm for ensuring quality (Wiklund et al. 2003 ; Sharma et al. 2010 ; Kasperavičiūtė-Černiauskienė and Serafinas 2018 ) while control is a determinant that investigative studies generally agree on but underscore in varying research foci. Examples of these control foci include institutional gatekeepers (Ferguson and Carnabuci 2017 ), institutional structures (Fischer and Tello-Gamarra 2017 ), institutional governance (Bekhet and Latif 2018 ), and internal control quality (Ruan and Liu 2021 ). However, the most stressed quality and control determinants are patent systems characterised by high levels of formalism (Barros 2015 ; Ervits and Zmuda 2018 ) and intended for managing Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) (Malva et al. 2013; Huang et al. 2017 ; Hou et al. 2018 ). An alternative but complementary perspective in the literature identifies ownership as a mechanism for quality (Yi et al. 2017 ) due to links with strategic human resource management that support innovation-oriented business strategies (Cooke and Saini 2010 ). Research also suggests that institutional strategies embed control in an array of managerial tools, such as institutional support systems that prioritise quality controls for shaping R&D efforts within innovation systems, especially in terms of labour productivity and patenting behaviour (Fischer and Tello-Gamarra 2017 ). In these circumstances, managerial sense-making (Lee and Yoo 2008 ; Weber et al. 2019 ) remains essential to achieving sound long-term performance, on which the legitimacy and sustainability of the selective governance constellation rest.

Although researchers agree on the importance of high performing and pro-innovation institutions, the spotlight on quality and control determinants tend to vary. Measuring efficacy and changeability offers the main interest for some researchers (Bennett and Nikolaev 2020 ; Afshari-Mofrad et al. 2021 ), while others analyse factors related to innovation performance (Asiedu et al. 2020 ; Bentzen et al. 2021 ; Godlewska 2021 ) or the performance of institutional entities such as firms (Li et al. 2020 ; Hussen and Çokgezen 2021 ), and universities (Sharma and Sharma 2021 ). The latter interest informs the use of analytical constructs like the quadruple helix, which add a layer of network control for engagement (Schütz et al. 2018 ; Kang and Jiang 2020 ). This layer taps into huge potentials for high quality collaborative innovation for confronting grand challenges (e.g., climate change and urban mobility) facing modern societies.

4.2 Institutional diversity and reputation

Next, institutional diversity and reputation offer the next category of determinants investigated by researchers. Here, the emphasis remains on understanding the roles of heterogeneous (de Zubielqui et al. 2015 ) and diverse (van Wijk et al. 2019 ) actors in mobilising the emotional energy and reflexive awareness necessary to disrupt the status quo, generate (and negotiate) alternatives, and embed solutions in institutional contexts to produce profound change. Diversity foci vary in several studies with interests including urban diversity (Smith and Thomas 2015 ), firm-university partnership diversity (Whitley 2014 ), and environmental technology diversity (Aragon-Correa and la Hiz 2016 ). These authors recognise variations in the idiosyncratic capabilities of firms for acquiring and allocating resources (Li 2015 ; Kang and He 2018 ) and how these capabilities influence the ability of institutions to generate environmental, social, and economic value for stakeholders (Yeung 2015 ). For some studies, inequality entrenched in long-standing institutional arrangements is a diversity management challenge for strategies to foster gender inclusivity (Krech 2020 ) and policies to redress social inequality and poverty (Zapata-Cantu and González 2021 ). More broadly, highlighted as a puzzle for management scholars, understanding the link between institutional innovation and inequality (Biurrun 2020 ) is a research focus accentuated by recent macroeconomic shocks due to the global financial crisis of 2007–2008 and COVID-19 pandemic. Due to these shocks and radical perturbations, some researchers (Tomizawa et al. 2020 ; Hughes et al. 2021 ) differ in their opinions on the role of diversity, arguing for emphasis on alternate inclusive institutional arrangements that foster inequality due to the breakdown of institutions stemming from major socio-economic and technological transformations in society.

In the literature, institutional reputation contains intrinsic ties to diversity (Wu et al. 2015 ) and indicates success (d’Agostino and Scarlato 2019 ). Reputation, in this context, concerns institutional (and organisational) credibility and integrity as viewed by a wide spectrum of stakeholders, including citizens, governmental agencies, customers, and industry. While strong institutional policies build reputation for top-down, up-and-up implementations, focus on organisational level reputation offers a bottom-up, divide-and-conquer alternative. Considering these prospects, researchers examine how carefully considered innovation strategies enable organisations to boost their reputation (Pesti et al. 2019 ) for attracting top talent (de la Mothe 2004 ; Dahm et al. 2021 ), and how institutional information and externalities influence institutional reputation (de Zubielqui et al. 2015 ).

4.3 Institutional value and output

Insights from the literature suggest that the category for institutional value and output offers the most investigated dependent variables for institutional innovation. In the context of institutions, some researchers with ‘contributory foci’ measure innovation outputs (e.g., using patent numbers and citations (Kim et al. 2019 ), revenues of new products (Hou et al. 2019 ), and costs of equity capital (Lui et al. 2016 ), while arguing that these outputs are part of a multi-faceted structure involving knowledge creation and diffusion (Kwan and Chiu 2015 ). In contrast, some studies with ‘critical foci’ investigate the decline of innovative outputs in the context of ties to policy efforts (Kunamaneni 2019 ), technology use (Mohsen et al. 2021 ), and the political economy of micro-level institutions (Haggard and Zheng 2013 ). There are also studies with ‘consequential foci’ examining the significance of the institutional environment from which organisations operate (Barasa et al. 2017 ) and the nature of collaboration between institutional entities (e.g., multinational companies and small-sized life science companies) for harnessing entrepreneurial and creative capacities (Styhre and Remneland-Wikhamn 2016 ).

Value, which is more inherently beneficiary-oriented and relational, also preoccupies researchers (Styhre and Remneland-Wikhamn 2016 ; Cestino and Berndt 2017 ), for public value creation that enhances the life of citizens (Yang 2016 ) and customer value propositions in transaction rules that benefit clients, buyers, end-users, and so on (Wallman 2009 ). Overall, determinants in this category strive for an integration of community indicators and government performance management in an iterative cycle of engagement, legitimacy, and execution, with structural developments across borders between civil society, politics, and administration.

4.4 Institutional reform and improvement

Institutional reform and improvement describe a category of determinants essential for transformative processes (i.e., methodical, management and process innovation) within institutions in such a way that different modus operandi and modus vivendi respect human rights, maintain the rule of law, and are accountable to constituents. Primarily the focus of earlier studies (Polopolus 1969 ; Ruttan and Hayami 1984 ; Grabowski 1988 ) and more recent discussions and conceptualisations (Sus 2019 ; Hughes et al. 2021 ; Perry 2021 ), interest in this category centres on discourse surrounding the genesis and metamorphosis of institutions. Earlier works stress the role of agents of change (Ebegbulem 1974 ; Pred 1978 ) while more recent expositions give prominence to the implementation of ambitious projects (Williams 2002 ; Chien 2007 ), and transparent public–private partnerships (Zhang and Tan 2019 ; Oppong and Andrews 2020 ; Yu 2020 ). Similarly, the nature of change varies among scholars with debates that highlight differing emphasis on socioeconomic and political change (Halpern 2005 ), change in the new power topology (Clapp et al. 2016 ), technological change (Mia 2020 ; Perry 2021 ), managerial change (Parrado 2008 ), and technical change for economic development and knowledge acquisition processes (Oyelaran-Oyeyinka 2006 ; Ruttan 2006 ). Some studies argue that reform for institutional improvement is crucial, not only to boost quality levels of outputs (Azadegan et al. 2013 ) but also procedurally to ensure quality exchanges within cooperative networks (Brinckmann 1998 ). However, other researchers offer a contrasting perspective that considers negative impacts of limits and constraints such as institutional voids in areas of inadequate support (Turker and Vural 2017 ), triggering a rethinking and reimagining of existing formal institutional frameworks (Onsongo 2019 ; Chebrolu and Dutta 2021 ).

Regional policies embed reform and deliver disruptive (hence economic) capabilities and capacities for improvements. In literature, capabilities tend to represent the most essential determinant in institutional innovation (Sawang et al. 2017 ), and even though this determinant spans different categories of determinants in literature as shown in Table 4 , the reform and improvement category heightens the role of capabilities. Insights from policy making and the development of technical standards advance this line of reasoning (Smink et al. 2015 ) as policy makers wrestle with necessary blends of heterogeneous actions (radical or incremental) (Turker and Vural 2017 ; Ventura et al. 2020 ), agents (internal or external) (Villavicencio et al. 2015 ), and arrangements (formal or informal) (Fischer and Tello-Gamarra 2017 ) for successful innovations. Capacities and other conditions for successful institutional reforms also preoccupy scholars with policy suggestions for eased foreign direct investment (McCarthy et al. 2014 ) and entrepreneurial endeavours that transcend the institutional constraints of national innovation systems (Hung 2000 ). Some studies view national and local reform in the context of structural and behavioural logics that legitimise social meanings required for reform and improvement (Lazer et al. 2011 ; Waldorff 2013 ; Kooijman et al. 2017 ), with scholars analysing speeds and directions of radical innovation. Although varied in focus, there is somewhat of a consensus on the role of reform and improvements for realising substantial economic growth, and for overcoming challenges of unemployment, inequality, and deprivation.

5 Management priorities for institutional innovation

Synthesis of review data finds six management priorities for enhancing institutional innovation. This review determines these priorities based on appraising management contributions within the literature. These priorities are: (i) network engagement, externalities, and relationships (NEER), (ii) institutional logic, capabilities, and constraints (ILCC), (iii) economic conditions, policies, and intermediaries (ECPI), (iv) institutional strategies, ownership, and governance (ISOG), (v) technology readiness, transfer, and support (TRTS), and (vi) institutional synergies, incentives, and entrepreneurship (ISIE). Table 5 summarises these priorities and the next subsections outline their importance.

5.1 Network engagement, externalities, and relationships

The first of the priorities, NEER, reflects the growing significance of managerial social networks for institutional innovation (Kraft and Bausch 2018 ) in relation to transdisciplinary and interdisciplinary engagement within institutional networks (Blättel-Mink and Kastenholz 2005 ; Moore 2011 ) and ecosystems (Boisvert et al. 2013 ). This thematic group considers dynamics of organisational networks (Hage and Hollingsworth 2000 ; Schøtt and Jensen 2016 ), domesticated market networks (Van Bockhaven et al. 2015 ), inter-organisational relations (Nooteboom 2000 ), innovation networks (Lyu et al. 2019 ), connectedness of regional institutions (Liu 2016 ), networking practices (Minh and Hjortsø 2015 ), and cohesive networks (Kraft and Bausch 2018 ). Here, there are management interests in social capital (Nieto and González-Álvarez 2014 ; Smith and Thomas 2015 ), social and institutional trust (Audretsch et al. 2018 ; Didenko et al. 2020 ), and relationship ties that include managerial ties (Gao et al. 2017 ; Ventura et al. 2020 ) and social ties (Chen et al. 2021 ).

Network partnerships within this theme consider managing interactions in public–private (Kidd 1996 ; Rosário et al. 2013 ), state-market (Yu 2020 ), and industry-academia (Krishnan and Jha 2012 ) partnerships. Literature also provides other network arrangements in the form of collaborations among industry, university, and research institutions (Yingbo et al. 2010 ), R&D collaborations (Hou et al. 2019 ), helix innovation networks (Schütz et al. 2018 ), public research institutions (Fritsch and Schwirten 1999 ), university-industry links (Kunamaneni 2019 ), and multi-level institutional linkages (Rodima-Taylor et al. 2012 ). Significant in institutional collaborations and partnerships is the role of institutional actors (Lounsbury and Crumley 2007 ; Chen 2018 ) who substantially influence the creation of new practice, innovation capability, commercialisation of new technology, and institutional arrangements. Specifically, research studies allude to network actors such as executive and middle managers (Radaelli et al. 2017 ), beneficiaries (Llopis and D’Este 2016 ), fierce competitors (Frey et al. 2012 ), suppliers (Nordberg et al. 2003 ), external actors (Sun et al. 2017 ), and elites (Geels 2004 ). These salient actors play a role in shaping innovation networks by influencing the preservation of socioeconomic order and investment in innovation. With this in mind, some studies concentrate on the multi-faceted nature of institutional actors through probes of actor perceptions, activities, and diversity (Lynn et al. 1996 ; van Wijk et al. 2019 ), institutional learning (Buttoud et al. 2011 ), and the increasing use of innovation ‘offshoring’ that creates global innovation networks (Desai 2009 ).

This theme also prioritises the management of institutional knowledge–related imperatives stemming from network interactions. Example of these imperatives are knowledge externalities (d’Agostino and Scarlato 2019 ), knowledge spirals (Sein-Echaluce et al. 2017 ), and knowledge acquisition (Rutherford 2001 ; Chittoor et al. 2015 ; Liao 2018 ) that influence innovation orientation. There are also interests in links between knowledge and creativity (Boudreaux 2017 ), new knowledge bases (Asheim and Coenen 2006 ; Rolfstam 2012 ), and the knowledge infrastructure that facilitates knowledge creation, diffusion, and accumulation in institutions (Hamdouch and Moulaert 2006 ; Gittelman 2006 ; Iqbal 2021 ).

5.2 Institutional logic, capabilities, and constraints

The second priority is ILCC , which encompasses configuration- and proficiency-related management for problem solving and optimising decisions under constraints. Contributions in this thematic grouping consider improvements in the configurations of institutional logic (Kooijman et al. 2017 ; Cinar and Benneworth 2021 ), institutional logic differences (Azadegan et al. 2013 ; Llopis and D’Este 2016 ), interplay of logics (Vickers et al. 2017 ), service dominant logic (SDL) and servitization (Cestino and Berndt 2017 ), and legacies (Baark 2007 ). Grounding these logics are distinctive capabilities (Kunamaneni 2019 ) in areas of governance structures (Rasiah et al. 2016 ), forecasting and planning of skilled labour (Gretchenko et al. 2018 ), institutional readiness (Webster and Gardner 2019 ), and so on. These sources offer a discourse suggesting diversity of capabilities as a source of innovative strength for institutions. Thus, context assumes an important role for institutional innovation with varying interests in institutional (Colwell and Narayanan 2010 ; Lindelöf 2011 ), country (Lee and Yoo 2008 ), and cultural (McCarthy et al. 2014 ; Piana et al. 2015 ) contexts.

Yet, empirical evidence suggests these positive enabling priorities may possess negative constraining concerns contingent on circumstances. For instance, there are studies on institutional inhibitors such as organisational slack (Malen and Vaaler 2017 ), institutional voids (Turker and Vural 2017 ; Onsongo 2019 ), and institutional misalignments (Bunduchi et al. 2015 ). This contradiction motivates studies on institutional environments with focus on corporate governance (Yi et al. 2012 ), and professional resistance (Radaelli et al. 2017 ). Institutional theory also posits on isomorphic, coercive, normative, and mimetic pressures as affecting environments that enact institutional innovation with interests in links with religion (Assouad and Parboteeah 2018 ), and alliances (Alexander 2012 ). The complexity of environments within which institutions operate also elevates the importance of designs for innovation systems and new international ventures (Hargrave and Van De Ven 2006 ; Boudreau and Lakhani 2016 ).

5.3 Economic conditions, policies, and intermediaries

ECPI is the next priority with themes detailing management of production and consumption conditions. Financial management lies at the heart of economic imperatives for commercialisation, investment, managerial incentives, costs, profitability, and shareholding in terms of institutional innovation. These imperatives motivate research interest, particularly in relation to financial (Vermeulen et al. 2007b ) and microfinance (Elle 2017 ) services for addressing concerns such as investment horizons (Kim et al. 2019 ), economic returns (Heher 2006 ), transaction costs (Aziz et al. 2019 ), and financial fraud (Yang et al. 2017 ). These constructs aid in examining innovation outputs (e.g., patents), composition of the firms in joint ventures, and investment objectives for incremental and radical innovation.

Economic policies are themes involving guidelines, procedures, or processes for achieving rational objectives and outcomes. Policies considered within the literature include public (Adebowale 2012 ; Doblinger et al. 2016 ; Allen et al. 2020 ), innovation (Liu et al. 2011 ; May and Schedelik 2019 ), community (Molnár 2004 ), institutional (Niosi 2010 ), technology (Harding 2000 ; George and Prabhu 2003 ; Vasudeva 2009 ), and antitrust (Hart 2001 ) policies. Effective management under these policies depend on legitimacy, investment efforts, risk-taking behaviour, technological stalemate, and evolutionary trajectories. Studies also identify institutional intermediaries (Watkins et al. 2015 ; Landoni 2017 ) and their economic impact on innovativeness for climate change, innovative capability for public procurement, brokering knowledge in networks, and commercialisation of technologies.

5.4 Institutional strategies, ownership, and governance

ISOG is the management priority that steers and coordinates efforts towards enhancing innovation levels and improving institutional performance. In this context, institutional innovation scholarship proposes governing procedures and practices in concepts of governance structure (Whitley 2000 ; Casper and Matraves 2003 ), governance institution quality (Bekhet and Latif 2018 ), financial governance (Hyvärinen 2006 ), corporate governance (Yoshikawa et al. 2007 ; Yang et al. 2017 ), participatory governance (Forde 2020 ; Kalinowski 2020 ), and institutional arbitrage (Clausen 2014 ). Challenges to empower stakeholders spur increasing shifts from government to governance (Nielsen et al. 2004 ; Clapp et al. 2016 ) with goals of gaining legitimacy from transformational and executive leadership that facilitates institutional change and reform (Williams 2002 ; Asiedu et al. 2020 ). The literature also accentuates institutional strategies (Brinckmann 1998 ; Villavicencio et al. 2015 ; Smink et al. 2015 ), legitimacy (Hung and Whittington 2011 ), open innovation strategies (Kitagawa and Robertson 2011 ; Smink et al. 2015 ; Abramov et al. 2019 ), strategic transactions and dialogue (Wallman 2009 ), offshoring innovation strategies (Sartor and Beamish 2014 ), and growth strategies (Koh 2006 ). For other scholars, ownership of rights and control serves as the foundation for strategies on institutional innovativeness. Here, the interest of research lies in the mechanisms that structure institutional ownership (Cooke and Saini 2010 ; Yi et al. 2017 ), equity ownership and institutional investors (Sakaki and Jory 2019 ), and state ownership (Yi et al. 2017 ).

5.5 Technology readiness, transfer, and support

The next management priority is TRTS , which plays a crucial role in institutional innovation levels and economic progress for countries (Clark 2002 ). The suggestion is that technology readiness to fulfil the needs of institutions remains a focal point for research (Webster and Gardner 2019 ; Markey-Towler 2020 ; Mohsen et al. 2021 ), and motivates studies on technology co-evolution, employment relations, institutional conflicts (Hung 2000 ; Costa and Horn 2021 ), and technological institutional reform (Clark 2002 ). In some technology readiness studies, researchers focus on technology development (Lee 2012 ) and available technological capabilities (la Hiz et al. 2019 ) for global innovations. Authors also explore institutional readiness in the context of technological foresight for facing future challenges (Quiroga and Martin 2017 ). From earlier emphasis on adoption and rejection stemming from institutional bandwagon pressures, the debate in the literature somewhat shifts to diffusion trajectories of continuous self-propagating technological innovation by institutions (Matzner 1985 ; Abrahamson and Rosenkopf 1993 ; Nagamatsu et al. 2006 ). Examples of these technologies include big data analytics (Yau and Lau 2018 ), telemedicine (Oborn et al. 2021 ), electronic cash transfers (Zhang and Putzel 2016 ), the Internet of Things (Xie and Yang 2021 ), and smart contracts based on financial technologies (Mishchenko et al. 2021 ).

In furtherance of readiness, technology transfer and support tend to play crucial roles in institutions of some emerging economies and sectors with low technological intensity. Empirical evidence in some studies link technology transfer to innovation diffusion patterns (Zweifel 1995 ; Kwon et al. 2009 ; Barbosa and Faria 2011 ) and knowledge transfer (Mason and Wagner 1999 ). Other studies consider internationalisation (Kumar et al. 2013 ; Suzuki 2015 ) and innovation offshoring (Rosenbusch et al. 2019 ) in the context of technological barriers and institutional arbitrage strategies. Within the literature, IPR is a technology-related concept crucial to supporting innovation. Here, the focus is on patents as a protection entity with research examining IPR in terms of geographical indicators (Juk and Fuck 2015 ), rights (Malva et al. 2013; Huang et al. 2017 ), sources (Abereijo et al. 2009 ), patent behaviour (Barros 2015 ), and domain-spanning patent applications (Ferguson and Carnabuci 2017 ). Management challenges confronted within existing IPR research for institutional innovation include patenting strategies, infringements of property rights, and new SME production and knowledge recombination strategies.

5.6 Institutional synergies, incentives, and entrepreneurship

The final priority is ISIE that influences the pooling of complementary resources for new ventures by institutions and institutional actors. Recognising the need for synergies to deliver new solutions and systems, researchers tend to agree on the need for co-creation (Kumari et al. 2020 ; Sharma and Sharma 2021 ), co-management (Léopold et al. 2019 ; Casagrande et al. 2021 ), and co-decisions for institutional resources (Shackleton and Raunio 2003 ). For instance, modern innovative drugs increasingly require co-development by pharmaceutical enterprises and scientific research institutions (Wang and Huang 2020 ). Thus, the complementary nature of institutions (Da Silva 2019 ), institutional roles (Garrick et al. 2011 ) and institutional arrangements (Lee and Yoo 2008 ; Corsi and Prencipe 2019 ), serves as foci for some studies seeking to improve integration and accountability in institutions.

Alternate perspectives note the need to manage convergence into cross-border innovations, symbiotic relationships, and collaborative agglomeration for regions (Singh and Allen 2006 ; Li and Xing 2020 ; Knickel et al. 2021 ). Technically, there are also enduring institutional challenges for co-generation e.g. of heat and electricity (Chartock et al. 1985 ). In these contexts, synergetic innovation serves as the mission for arrangements such as industry-university-research collaboration (Xu et al. 2020 ), and public–private partnership (Zhang and Tan 2019 ; Cechin et al. 2021 ).

For some scholars, entrepreneurship is the cornerstone of strategies for institutional innovation. However, these authors vary in their underlying viewpoints, with interests in institutional entrepreneurs (Wang and Swanson 2007 ; Jensen and Fersch 2019 ), entrepreneur roles (Tumbas et al. 2018 ), entrepreneurial mind-sets (Cowden and Bendickson 2018 ), the influence of quality on entrepreneurship (Veiga et al. 2020 ), and interfaces between entrepreneurship and marketing (Laurell 2018 ). Irrespective of the viewpoint, the necessity- and opportunity-based nature of entrepreneurs guides researchers in positing and analysing entrepreneurship links with economic growth (Galindo-Martín et al. 2020 ). Closely linked to motivating entrepreneurial endeavours within institutions is the role of incentives, which literature links to the overcoming of market failures (Tang et al. 2020b ) and the implementation of regulations (Costa-Font and Puig-Junoy 2007 ). In the literature, there are additional accounts on the importance of executive incentives (Wang and Deng 2021 ), producers’ incentives (Desmet et al. 2020 ), incentive properties of income-sharing arrangements (Tyson 1979 ), and managerial incentives (Hyvärinen 2006 ; Jun and Weare 2011 ; Tang et al. 2020a ). Yet, it is worth noting that the presence of conflicting incentives may ultimately undermine innovation efforts (Carney and Zheng 2009 ).

6 Future research directions for institutional innovation scholarship

Using insights from the literature, this review contributes to research by proposing a multi-level model for managing institutional innovation, as shown by Fig.  5 . Premised on a background of literature arguing for induced, collective, and continuous genesis of institutional innovation, and supported by injections or ‘pumps’ of investments, the model advances knowledge by summarising the findings of the review in terms of key institutional determinants and management priorities. The main argument of the model is that innovation contexts shape the key determinants within institutions and that these determinants influence management priorities for institutional innovation. Our multi-level framing of priorities, determinants, and contexts, offers a set of factors that adds to the discourse concerning the need for more holistic assessments of institutional foundations, which current research elaborates in the form of deep institutional foci (Hughes et al. 2021 ), and co-evolution processes (Costa and Horn 2021 ). However, in practice, far from suggesting a panacea for managing the challenges and opportunities in institutions, the model, through the systematic insights from the literature, offers a research perspective on potential critical factors for stage-managing and enacting organisational, social, environmental, and governmental changes via contracts, internalisation, regulation, and referendums. In this section, we use insights from the review to set a research agenda that entails three potential paths for future research.

figure 5

Multi-level management model of Institutional Innovation

To begin with, a critique of the theoretical and methodological space in literature provides the first path for future studies. In this context, in current studies and as shown in Fig.  4 b, the balance of the theoretical base appears tilted towards institution-oriented theories, particularly institutional theory treated in 95 studies. This raises the prospect for more innovation studies to offset this imbalance by testing existing innovation theories (e.g., diffusion of innovation) in different contexts, examining theories with limited coverage (e.g., the Bass model) in an institutional milieu, and proposing new theories. Current determinants analysed from the review mainly consider the institutional aspects for innovation, as shown by Sect.  4 . Thus, examinations driven by more framings of innovation could generate new insights on potential innovation-oriented determinants such as creativity, mindfulness, foresight, innovative climate, etc. Methodologically , researchers seem to favour case studies, surveys, essays, and econometric analysis. To a lesser extent, the review indicates interest in the use of decision analysis, meta-analysis, action research, and field experiments. Thus, there is a need for further investigations of the conceptual space for institution innovation using lesser-applied methods along with studies applying novel methods such ethnography, online research, meta-synthesis, phenomenography, and grounded theory. Existing management priorities in the literature mainly reflect macro- and meso-level considerations of institutional innovation, particularly in the context of regional, national, sectoral, and organisational concerns. Accordingly, there is a need for further studies of micro-level considerations, i.e., individual factors that enable or inhibit institutional innovation. For instance, grounded theory or ethnography-based studies could explore and theorise on personas, personalities, and motivations of institutional actors that play major roles in inducing, coordinating collective action, or championing continuous change. Similarly, online research or phenomenography could underpin explorations on the role and factors of technology (e.g., social media) use by institutional actors in relation to embedded and established routines for innovation stages (e.g., ideation) in institutions.

In line with current studies, this review challenges researchers to explore policy void in industrialised and social contexts (Mehmood 2016 ; Onsongo 2019 ) and investigate the role of institutional mediators and factors (Laurell 2018 ; Tomizawa et al. 2020 ) in relation to institutional adaptation for regional innovations. There are also challenges to detangle institutional variations concerning how formal and informal institutions shape innovation types, practices, and processes (Chadee and Roxas 2013 ; Filiou and Golesorkhi 2016 ; Huang et al. 2017 ). Further challenges exist regarding the multi-faceted role of institutional environments that positively endorse and enable, or negatively inhibit and inactivate institutional innovations (Whitley 2000 ; Wang and Swanson 2007 ; Mueller et al. 2013 ; Wu et al. 2016 ; Fischer and Tello-Gamarra 2017 ; Nite and Washington 2017 ; Kadriu et al. 2019 ; Wu and Park 2019 ).

Derived from reflections on the management priorities of the previous section, the third path for future studies extends the synthesis from the review for topical viewpoints that strategically advance the field of institutional innovation. In the next subsections, we present these paths, detail current related efforts, and elaborate on some specific research challenges for management scholarship concerning institutional innovation.

6.1 Institutional contracting

The first challenge involves studies of institutional contracting (mainly from reflections on NEER ) that examine the process of engagement, building relationships, and bargaining with contractors for formulating and implementing contracts. Accordingly, studies of institutional contracting advance NEER management, and in the proposed model of Fig.  5 , NEER management maintains social exchanges within institutions in accordance with contingency, agency, and transaction cost theories. With increasing global trends towards privatisation, urbanisation, internationalisation, and digitalisation, the indications are that contracts remain crucial for maintaining transdisciplinary and interdisciplinary engagement within institutions. In current literature, new forms of contracts serve as the focus of innovation by agricultural institutions for contract farming (Escobal 2000 ; Bhanot et al. 2021 ) and supplier contracts with research institutions (Nordberg et al. 2003 ). There are also discussions on the value of smart contracts developed by financial institutions (Mishchenko et al. 2021 ). Although contracts are well-established as a form of institutional innovation (Polopolus 1969 ), studies on the nature of contracting remains limited. Therefore, we urge for research exploring the nature of contracting that enables institutional innovation and critical success factors of this contracting process. With evidence suggesting that contract enforcement challenges may cause the emergence of new institutions (Dimitri 2002 ), future research could theorise on and empirically investigate enforcement mechanisms for sourcing and contracting institutional innovation. Research also suggests that inadequate contracting processes account for several regulatory failures (Costa-Font and Puig-Junoy 2007 ), challenging future studies to expand on normative frameworks for contracting within institutions.

6.2 Institutional reimagining

The next challenge relates to research on institutional reimagining (from reflections on ILCC ) to offer a critical view that complements existing analytical insights from studying opportunities and challenges of induced, continuous, and collective institutional innovation. Hence, research on institutional reimagining furthers ILCC management, and in the proposed model of Fig.  5 , ILCC management involves coordinating capabilities under institutional constraints that reflect resource-based, dynamic capabilities, absorptive capacities, and institutional-pump framings. This coordination requires awareness and support for the construction of institutional narratives (Schofield 2000 ) and consciousness capabilities of new global imaginaries (Hughes et al. 2021 ). In furtherance of these efforts, we propose that researchers assess institutions critically on an on-going basis to promote transdisciplinary efforts that avert institutional stagnation when confronting societal challenges. With insights from the literature and in line with institutional theory, this review highlights the need for critical reflections on the measures and pressures that shape innovation success. Multi-level analysis could aid in uncovering the micro, meso, and macro levels that are critical to promoting success and averting collapse of institutions. Critiques could also compare up-and-up and divide-and-conquer strategic plans to highlight instances of wasteful tax-and-spend policies.

Recognising the threat of institutional obsolescence discussed in early research (Polopolus 1969 ; Shaffer 1969 ), we also propose future research on the collapse of institutions, in the context of failed institutional logics for innovation to capture reasons, detail lessons learnt, review existing policy toolboxes, and reimagine failed institutions. For instance, the collapse of financial institutions in 2008 and economic collapse due to the COVID-19 are instances of institutional collapse with negative global consequences. Thus, this line of research could strive to analyse innovation determinants for recovery or reconstruction of institutions. Questions guiding such research efforts include ‘how can governments innovatively reconstruct collapsed institutions?’ and ‘what structural and behavioural attributes contribute to the collapse of institutions?’ Future research could also use insights from lessons learnt to provide innovative forecasting tools to avert institutional collapse.

6.3 Institutional intelligence

Another challenge for studies involves analysing institutional intelligence (from reflections on ECPI ). Research concerning institutional intelligence encompasses assessments of the data analytic capacities (e.g. big data analytics (Yau and Lau 2018 )) that harness the potentials of institutional information, and the intelligent intermediaries (Chen et al. 2015 ) that facilitate innovation, particularly in relation to recruiting, retaining, and developing intelligent employees. Consequently, institutional intelligence research advances ECPI management, which represents a fundamental component of the proposed multi-level management model, as represented by Fig.  5 , and determines economic benefits from institutional innovation, in line with economic theory. Although, this review incorporates studies on the need to attract top talent for innovative research in higher education (Dahm et al. 2021 ) and innovation ‘offshoring’ to emerging countries (Desai 2009 ), this line of inquiry remains limited in the context of institutional innovation research. Accordingly, we challenge academia to explore the range of data analytics for institutional innovation further, along with concepts such as institutional optimisation, innovative talent capacity building, institutional intelligence, and talent management strategies. Studies may also consider intelligence and talent management in relation to roles of actors in constructs like the quadruple helix, and control mechanisms, e.g., managerial incentives and corporate governance. Since intelligence and talent are human capital constructs, there are questions concerning effectiveness of top-down and bottom-up strategies within institutions. Some questions include ‘how effective is upper management in retaining talent for innovation?’ and ‘what is nature of team involvement in selecting and sourcing analytic capabilities for institutional innovation?’.

6.4 Institutional stewardship

For management researchers, there are future opportunities to examine institutional stewardship (mainly from reflections on ISOG ). With emphasis on responsibility and accountability, stewardship progresses ISOG management and embodies the control and sense of duty demanded by on-going shifts from government to governance (Clapp et al. 2016 ) for boosting participation and empowerment for institutional innovation. ISOG management, in the proposed model of Fig.  5 , involves governance that promotes pro-innovation institutions and is in line with agency and actor network theories. In this review, studies offer insights on related challenges for participatory governance (Forde 2020 ) and leadership (Williams 2002 ; Asiedu et al. 2020 ) that trend towards a sense of duty by institutional actors. Despite these research efforts, the literature provides limited bottom-up insights on the potential role of stewards in promoting institutional innovation and innovation contexts, i.e., organisational, environmental, social, and governmental. Future research could study specific roles of institutional stewards for radial and incremental innovations. Although, empirical evidence suggests links between stewardship behaviour and the success of innovation (Domínguez-Escrig et al. 2019 ), there are opportunities for studies to test this relationship in normative and cognitive institutional contexts. Future research may also view challenges of institutional stewardship in isolation or in conjunction with existing inadequacies due to institutional pressures, voids, and barriers.

6.5 Institutional preparedness

Another potential research direction involves studies of institutional preparedness (mainly from reflections on TRTS ), in the context of more frequently occurring macroeconomic shocks and technological transformations in society that threaten the legitimacy of institutions. Traditionally a focus of studies on agents of change (Ebegbulem 1974 ), research on readiness in an institutional context increasingly focuses on preparedness that supports trajectories of self-propagating technologies (Nagamatsu et al. 2006 ). Institutional preparedness, in this context, refers to how institutions are equipped in terms of capabilities and capacities to respond to new challenges and opportunities. The proposed multi-level model of Fig.  5 advances TRTS management for technology readiness as an element of institutional preparedness, with conceptual underpinnings from contingency and diffusion theory. Yet, there remain challenges to understand future innovation contexts and preparedness by institutions for praxis and crisis situations, proactively and reactively. For instance, recent dengue, Zika, and coronavirus outbreaks have challenged the role of traditional innovation-driven approaches, which focus on opportunity, and shifted the attention to ingenuity to cope with adversity. In addition, there are challenges to examine the infusion and routinisation (beyond the adoption and diffusion foci of current research (e.g., Genus 2012 ; Oborn et al. 2021 )) of technologies emerging due to the Fourth Industrial Revolution (e.g., synthetic data, biotechnology, and 3D printing). Thus, future studies may consider challenges such as institutional roadmaps with foresights for emerging technologies and institutional skilling needs. Other investigations could consider preparedness constructs for innovative institutions and crisis-driven innovation contexts for institutions.

6.6 Institutional complementarities

The final challenge involves research on institutional complementarities (mainly from reflections on ISIE ) for examining the ability of institutions to supplement other institutions in the quest for innovation, or the degree to which institutional arrangements, roles, factors, and innovation emphasise or improve each other. Just as innovation complements other explanations of economic growth (e.g., geography, and international trade), opportunities exist to investigate the complementarities for institutional innovation. For this reason, studies of institutional complementarities further ISIE management, and in the proposed model of Fig.  5 , ISIE management ensures integration and incentivisation within institutions in accordance with resource-based and dynamic capabilities views. Discussions in the literature on compatibility and substitutability (Corsi and Prencipe 2019 ; Da Silva 2019 ) reinforce the role of strategies for complementarities in sustaining synergies and incentivising entrepreneurial ventures within institutions. Yet, questions remain on the scope, range, and forms of complementarities that facilitate institutional innovation. For instance, the prospect of ‘creative complementarities’ that supply creativity-driven resources and know-how (Durugbo et al. 2020a ), suggests possibilities for implementation, adoption, and continuance forms of complementarities that incentivise induced, continuous, and collective institutional innovation. Lines of inquiry could examine the nature of complementarities that (dis)incentivise entrepreneurial endeavours within institutions. Such focus is needed because the literature in this review suggests that conflicting incentives within institutions inevitably deter innovative activities (Carney and Zheng 2009 ). Further studies could also examine institutional complementariness for innovation in the context of determinants such as quality, productivity, diversity, and so on. In addition, complementary viewpoints may consider and explore the role of complementarities in addressing challenges of inequality, sustainability, security etc.

7 Conclusions

In the words of Pablo Picasso, “learn the rules like a pro, so you can break them like an artist”. This saying underscores the need for ingenuity and innovation by institutions, as the rules of societies or of organisations to deliver value for a range of stakeholders such as citizens, governmental agencies, customers, and industry. Additionally, innovation in an institutional milieu faces pressures, voids, and barriers that force institutions to shift from scalable efficiency to scalable learning in efforts to expand management strategy and policy horizons. Consequently, transdisciplinary insights on the key determinants and management priorities of institutional innovation are critical to cope with the inherent dynamic nature and tension between institutional persistence and innovative practices. These determinants and priorities aid institutions deliver breakthrough processes and outcomes that require review on an on-going basis to update scholarship and practice. With this in mind, this review confronts the following research question: “What are the main determinants and management priorities of institutional innovation in the literature?” ( RQ ).

Driven by a systematic approach that seeks to address RQ , this review summarises its findings in a multi-level management model for institutional innovation in terms of innovation contexts, institutional determinants, and management priorities. Grounded on organisational, social, environmental, and governmental contexts for innovation, the review identified four key determinants concerning (i) innovation quality and control; (ii) institutional diversity and reputation; (iii) innovation value and output; and (iv) institutional reform and improvement. Similarly, the review captured six management priorities concerning network engagement, externalities, and relationships; institutional logic, capabilities, and constraints; economic conditions, policies, and intermediaries; institutional strategies, ownership, and governance; and technology readiness, transfer, and support; and institutional synergies, incentives, and entrepreneurship.

There are two main limitations of this review. First, the review focus is limited to capturing the main determinants and management priorities of institutional innovation. In this context, there is a need for additional insights on aspects such as innovation activities, the behaviour of institutional actors, and institutional arrangements. Second, the review approach is restricted to a systematic methodology that applies thematic analysis. Hence, there are prospects for deeper insights based on other review methodologies such as meta-analyses and meta-syntheses that offer more focused and extensive knowledge on constructs, dependencies, and links between variables within qualitative and quantitative studies of institutional innovation. Further analysis of co-citations could offer knowledge on the nature of citation dynamics and potential connections between publications.

Guided by insights from the findings on management priorities, the review identifies six strategic areas for future management research on institutional contracting, reimagining, intelligence, stewardship, preparedness, and complementarities. In summary, the review anticipates that the necessities and niceties of these proposed areas will aid in strengthening existing knowledge on institutional innovation and in uncovering new and exciting institutional phenomena, prospects, and potentials as managers set ground rules on contexts for innovation and run the rule over determinants within institutions.

Innovation is defined here according to the 2018 Oslo Manual as an outcome (business innovation), i.e. “new or improved product or business process (or combination thereof) that differs significantly from the firm's previous products or business processes and that has been introduced on the market or brought into use by the firm”, and as a process (innovation activities), i.e. “developmental, financial and commercial activities undertaken by a firm that are intended to result in an innovation for the firm” (OECD/Eurostat 2018; p. 33).

Network of actors from academia, industry, government, and the public.

Abereijo IO, Adegbite SA, Ilori MO et al (2009) Technological innovation sources and institutional supports for manufacturing small and medium enterprises in Nigeria. J Technol Manag Innov 4:82–89. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-27242009000200007

Article   Google Scholar  

Abrahamson E, Rosenkopf L (1993) Institutional and competitive bandwagons: Using mathematical modeling as a tool to explore innovation diffusion. Acad Manag Rev 18:487. https://doi.org/10.2307/258906

Abramov RA, Sokolov MS, Derevianko SV (2019) Institutional framework for entrepreneurship of regional innovation systems of the union state. Acad Entrep J 25:1–6

Google Scholar  

Adebowale BOA (2012) Innovation policies institutions and performance: Why Malaysia overtook Nigeria in the oil palm industry. Int J Technol Learn Innov Dev 5:126–157. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTLID.2012.044880

Adomssent M, Michelsen G (2006) German Academia heading for sustainability? Reflections on policy and practice in teaching, research and institutional innovations. Environ Educ Res 12:85–99. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504620500527758

Afshari-Mofrad M, Ghazinoory S, Nasri S (2021) Measuring the efficiency, effectiveness and changeability of institutions for improving national innovation system. Asian J Technol Innov 29:233–257. https://doi.org/10.1080/19761597.2020.1797517

Agarwal B (2020) A tale of two experiments: institutional innovations in women’s group farming in India. Can J Dev Stud 41:169–192. https://doi.org/10.1080/02255189.2020.1779673

Aguilera-Caracuel J, Ortiz-de-Mandojana N (2013) Green innovation and financial performance: an institutional approach. Organ Environ 26:365–385. https://doi.org/10.1177/1086026613507931

Alamad S, Hidayah NN, Lowe A (2021) A shared boundary object: financial innovation and engineering in Islamic financial institutions. Br Account Rev. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bar.2020.100958

Albertini S, Muzzi C (2016) Institutional entrepreneurship and organizational innovation: The start-up of a divergent new venture at the periphery of a mature field. Int J Entrep Innov 17:110–119. https://doi.org/10.1177/1465750316648578

AlEssa HS, Durugbo CM (2021) Systematic review of innovative work behavior concepts and contributions. Manag Rev Q. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11301-021-00224-x

Alexander EA (2012) The effects of legal, normative, and cultural-cognitive institutions on innovation in technology alliances. Manag Int Rev 52:791–815. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11575-011-0123-y

Allen DWE, Berg C, Markey-Towler B et al (2020) Blockchain and the evolution of institutional technologies: Implications for innovation policy. Res Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2019.103865

Ananthram S, Chan C (2021) Institutions and frugal innovation: the case of Jugaad. Asia Pacific J Manag 38:1031–1060. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-019-09700-1

Andersen J, Bilfeldt A (2017) Transforming welfare institutions through social innovation and action research in Denmark. Int J Action Res 13:201–220. https://doi.org/10.3224/ijar.v13i3.02

Andrew D (2012) Institutional policy innovation in aviation. J Air Transp Manag 21:36–39. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jairtraman.2011.12.015

Antonova NE, Lomakina NV (2020) Institutional innovations for the development of the east of Russia: Effects of implementation in the resource region. J Sib Fed Univ - Humanit Soc Sci 13:442–452. https://doi.org/10.17516/1997-1370-0580

Aragon-Correa JA, la Hiz DI (2016) The influence of technology differences on corporate environmental patents: a resource-based versus an institutional view of green innovations. Bus Strateg Environ 25:421–434. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.1885

Arranz N, Arguello NL, de Arroyabe JC (2021) How do internal, market and institutional factors affect the development of eco-innovation in firms? J Clean Prod. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.126692

Arribas JMG (2020) Centers of vocational excellence and innovation (CoVes): a new era for vocational education and training (VET) institutions? Acad 2020:58–84

Arun TM, Joseph RP, Ul Akram M (2020) Entrepreneur’s gender and firm innovation breadth: an institution-based view of SMEs in an emerging market context. Int J Innov Manag 24:2050068. https://doi.org/10.1142/S1363919620500681

Asheim BT, Coenen L (2006) Contextualising regional innovation systems in a globalising learning economy: on knowledge bases and institutional frameworks. J Technol Transf 31:163–173. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-005-5028-0

Asiedu MA, Anyigba H, Ofori KS et al (2020) Factors influencing innovation performance in higher education institutions. Learn Organ 27:365–378. https://doi.org/10.1108/TLO-12-2018-0205

Assouad A, Parboteeah KP (2018) Religion and innovation. A country institutional approach. J Manag Spiritual Relig 15:20–37. https://doi.org/10.1080/14766086.2017.1378589

Audretsch DB, Seitz N, Rouch KM (2018) Tolerance and innovation: the role of institutional and social trust. Eurasian Bus Rev 8:71–92. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-017-0086-4

Azadegan A, Napshin S, Oke A (2013) The influence of R&D partnerships on innovation in manufacturing firms: The moderating role of institutional attachment. Int J Oper Prod Manag 33:248–274. https://doi.org/10.1108/01443571311300755

Aziz MA, Din BH, Abdulsomad K (2019) Transaction costs of the zakat institution: an open innovation approach. Institutions Econ 11:43–71

Baark E (2007) Knowledge and innovation in China: Historical legacies and emerging institutions. Asia Pacific Bus Rev 13:337–356. https://doi.org/10.1080/13602380701291917

Bahlmann J, Spiller A (2009) The effect of institutional innovations on food chain governance: a case study on the shifting role of the German QS system from certification to supply chain coordination. J Chain Netw Sci 9:89–103. https://doi.org/10.3920/JCNS2009.x173

Baker R (1989) Institutional innovation, development and environmental management: An ‘administrative trap’ revisited. Part II Public Adm Dev 9:29–47. https://doi.org/10.1002/pad.4230090206

Bakir C, Gunduz KA (2017) When, why and how institutional change takes place: a systematic review and a future research agenda on the importance of policy entrepreneurship in macroeconomic bureaucracies. Policy Soc 36:479–503. https://doi.org/10.1080/14494035.2017.1369676

Balthasar A, Bättig C, Thierstein A, Wilhelm B (2000) “Developers”: key actors of the innovation process. Types of developers and their contacts to institutions involved in research and development, continuing education and training, and the transfer of technology. Technovation 20:523–538. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0166-4972(99)00180-7

Barasa L, Knoben J, Vermeulen P et al (2017) Institutions, resources and innovation in East Africa: a firm level approach. Res Policy 46:280–291. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.11.008

Barbosa N, Faria AP (2011) Innovation across Europe: how important are institutional differences? Res Policy 40:1157–1169. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.05.017

Barros HM (2015) Exploring the use of patents in a weak institutional environment: The effects of innovation partnerships, firm ownership, and new management practices. Technovation 45–46:63–77. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2015.05.003

Batukova LR, Bezrukikh DV, Senashov SI et al (2019) Modernization and innovation: economic and institutional role. Espacios 40:1–16

Bekhet HA, Latif NWA (2018) The impact of technological innovation and governance institution quality on Malaysia’s sustainable growth: Evidence from a dynamic relationship. Technol Soc 54:27–40. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2018.01.014

Bello DC, Lohtia R, Sangtani V (2004) An institutional analysis of supply chain innovations in global marketing channels. Ind Mark Manag 33:57–64. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2003.08.011

Bennett DL, Nikolaev B (2020) Individualism, pro-market institutions, and national innovation. Small Bus Econ. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-020-00396-y

Bentzen E, Freij Å, Varnes CJ (2021) The role of flexibility and complexity in response to regulatory change: a case study of innovation in a major Danish financial institution. Int J Entrep Innov. https://doi.org/10.1177/1465750320987929

Berraies S, Achour M, Chaher M (2015) Focusing the mediating role of knowledge management practices: How does institutional and interpersonal trust support exploitative and exploratory innovation? J Appl Bus Res 31:1479–1492. https://doi.org/10.19030/jabr.v31i4.9331

Berrone P, Fosfuri A, Gelabert L, Gomez-Mejia LR (2013) Necessity as the mother of “green” inventions: Institutional pressures and environmental innovations. Strateg Manag J 34:891–909. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2041

Beunen R, Kole S (2021) Institutional innovation in conservation law: experiences from the implementation of the birds and habitats directives in the Netherlands. Land Use Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2021.105566

Bhanot D, Kathuria V, Das D (2021) Can institutional innovations in agri-marketing channels alleviate distress selling? Evidence from India World Dev. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105202

Bierut BK, Dybka P (2021) Increase versus transformation of exports through technological and institutional innovation: evidence from Bayesian model averaging. Econ Model. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2021.105501

Biggs S (2008) Learning from the positive to reduce rural poverty and increase social justice: Institutional innovations in agricultural and natural resources research and development. Exp Agric 44:37–60. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0014479707005959

Bin A, Gianoni C, Mendes PJV et al (2013) Organization of research and innovation: a comparative study of public agricultural research institutions. J Technol Manag Innov 8:209–218. https://doi.org/10.4067/s0718-27242013000300048

Biurrun A (2020) New evidence toward solving the puzzle of innovation and inequality. The role of institutions. Econ Innov New Technol. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2020.1853659

Bjornlund H, van Rooyen A, Pittock J et al (2020) Institutional innovation and smart water management technologies in small-scale irrigation schemes in southern Africa. Water Int 45:621–650. https://doi.org/10.1080/02508060.2020.1804715

Blake JIR, Boyd SW, Phillips HJ et al (2021) A celebration of academic and industry collaboration: the royal national lifeboat institution and maritime engineering innovation. Proc Inst Mech Eng Part M J Eng Marit Environ 235:844–853. https://doi.org/10.1177/1475090220937901

Blättel-Mink B, Kastenholz H (2005) Transdisciplinarity in sustainability research: diffusion conditions of an institutional innovation. Int J Sustain Dev World Ecol 12:1–12. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504500509469613

Boisvert V, Méral P, Froger G (2013) Market-based instruments for ecosystem services: institutional innovation or renovation? Soc Nat Resour 26:1122–1136. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920.2013.820815

Boroujerdi SS, Hasani K, Delshab V (2020) Investigating the influence of knowledge management on organizational innovation in higher educational institutions. Kybernetes 49:442–459. https://doi.org/10.1108/K-09-2018-0492

Boudreau KJ, Lakhani KR (2016) Innovation experiments: researching technical advance, knowledge production, and the design of supporting institutions. Innov Policy Econ 16:135–167. https://doi.org/10.1086/684988

Boudreaux CJ (2017) Institutional quality and innovation: some cross-country evidence. J Entrep Public Policy 6:26–40. https://doi.org/10.1108/JEPP-04-2016-0015

Boulanger P-P, Gagnon C (2018) Financial innovation and institutional voices in the Canadian press: a look at the roaring 2000s. Int J Bus Commun 55:383–405. https://doi.org/10.1177/2329488417747596

Brinckmann H (1998) Infrastructure and tools for successful institutional innovation. Tert Educ Manag 4:48–58. https://doi.org/10.1080/13583883.1998.9966945

Buchheim L, Krieger A, Arndt S (2020) Innovation types in public sector organizations: a systematic review of the literature. Manag Rev Q 70:509–533. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11301-019-00174-5

Buck RC, Rath RA (1970) Planning as institutional innovation in the smaller city. J Am Plan Assoc 36:59–64. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944367008977281

Bunda NR, Spatariu EC, Popovici N (2014) The institutional framework and innovation levels in EU countries. Transform Bus Econ 13:584–601

Bunduchi R, Smart A, Charles K et al (2015) When innovation fails: an institutional perspective of the (non)adoption of boundary spanning IT innovation. Inf Manag 52:563–576. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.im.2015.04.001

Buszard D, Kolb J (2011) Institutional innovation to deliver post-secondary education for sustainability. Sustain J Rec 4:80–84. https://doi.org/10.1089/SUS.2011.9706

Buttoud G, Kouplevatskaya-Buttoud I, Slee B, Weiss G (2011) Barriers to institutional learning and innovations in the forest sector in Europe: Markets, policies and stakeholders. For Policy Econ 13:124–131. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2010.05.006

Carlsson B (1997) Technological systems and industrial dynamics. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Massachusetts

Book   Google Scholar  

Carney RW, Zheng LY (2009) Institutional (dis)incentives to innovate: an explanation for Singapore’s innovation gap. J East Asian Stud 9:291–319. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1598240800003015

Casagrande A, Salvatore R, Rover OJ et al (2021) Artisanal mollusc fisheries co-management in Brazil and Italy: Institutional innovations to address environmental crisis. J Environ Manage. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.112671

Casper S, Matraves C (2003) Institutional frameworks and innovation in the German and UK pharmaceutical industry. Res Policy 32:1865–1879. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(03)00082-9

Cechin A, da Silva AV, Amand L (2021) Exploring the synergy between community supported agriculture and agroforestry: institutional innovation from smallholders in a brazilian rural settlement. J Rural Stud 81:246–258. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2020.10.031

Cestino J, Berndt A (2017) Institutional limits to service dominant logic and servitisation in innovation efforts in newspapers. J Media Bus Stud 14:188–216. https://doi.org/10.1080/16522354.2018.1445163

Chadee D, Roxas B (2013) Institutional environment, innovation capacity and firm performance in Russia. Crit Perspect Int Bus 9:19–39. https://doi.org/10.1108/17422041311299923

Chartock MA, Devine MD, Gunn EM (1985) Institutional innovation for cogeneration. Rev Policy Res 5:89–95. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-1338.1985.tb00012.x

Chebrolu SP, Dutta D (2021) Managing sustainable transitions: Institutional innovations from india. Sustain. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13116076

Chen G (2018) Social sharing institution of SMEs’ technology innovation risk. IPPTA Q J Indian Pulp Pap Tech Assoc 30:323–330

Chen S-H, Egbetokun AA, Chen D-K (2015) Brokering knowledge in networks: Institutional intermediaries in the Taiwanese biopharmaceutical innovation system. Int J Technol Manag 69:189–209. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTM.2015.072978

Chen W, Han C, Wang L et al (2021) Recognition of entrepreneur’s social ties and firm innovation in emerging markets: explanation from the industrial institutional environment and survival pressure. Asia Pacific J Manag 38:491–518. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-019-09680-2

Chen X, Yi N, Zhang L, Li D (2018) Does institutional pressure foster corporate green innovation? Evidence from China’s top 100 companies. J Clean Prod 188:304–311. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.03.257

Chhetri N, Chaudhary P, Tiwari PR, Yadaw RB (2012) Institutional and technological innovation: understanding agricultural adaptation to climate change in Nepal. Appl Geogr 33:142–150. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apgeog.2011.10.006

Chien S-S (2007) Institutional innovations, asymmetric decentralization, and local economic development: a case study of Kunshan, in Post-Mao China. Environ Plan C Gov Policy 25:269–290. https://doi.org/10.1068/c0558

Chittoor R, Aulakh PS, Ray S (2015) Accumulative and assimilative learning, institutional infrastructure, and innovation orientation of developing economy firms. Glob Strateg J 5:133–153. https://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.1093

Chu Z, Xu J, Lai F, Collins BJ (2018) Institutional theory and environmental pressures: the moderating effect of market uncertainty on innovation and firm performance. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 65:392–403. https://doi.org/10.1109/TEM.2018.2794453

Cinar R, Benneworth P (2021) Why do universities have little systemic impact with social innovation? An institutional logics perspective. Growth Change 52:751–769. https://doi.org/10.1111/grow.12367

Clapp A, Hayter R, Affolderbach J, Guzman L (2016) Institutional thickening and innovation: reflections on the remapping of the Great Bear Rainforest. Trans Inst Br Geogr 41:244–257. https://doi.org/10.1111/tran.12119

Clark GL, Monk AHB (2016) Ambiguity, contract, and innovation in financial institutions. Compet Chang 20:187–203. https://doi.org/10.1177/1024529416635930

Clark N (2002) Innovation systems, institutional change and the new knowledge market: Implications for third world agricultural development. Econ Innov New Technol 11:353–368. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438590200000004

Clark N, Clay E (1987) The dryland research project at indore (1974–1980)—an institutional innovation in rural technology transfer. J Rural Stud 3:159–173. https://doi.org/10.1016/0743-0167(87)90031-3

Clausen TH (2014) The role of institutional arbitrage in the search for product innovation: firm level evidence from Norway. Ind Mark Manag 43:392–399. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2013.12.007

Colwell K, Narayanan VK (2010) Foresight in economic development policy: shaping the institutional context for entrepreneurial innovation. Futures 42:295–303. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.futures.2009.11.015

Considine M, Lewis JM (2007) Innovation and innovators inside government: From institutions to networks. Governance 20:581–607. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0491.2007.00373.x

Cooke FL, Saini DS (2010) (How) Does the HR strategy support an innovation oriented business strategy? An investigation of institutional context and organizational practices in Indian firms. Hum Resour Manage 49:377–400. https://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.20356

Cooke P, Uranga MG, Etxebarria G (1997) Regional innovation systems: Institutional and organisational dimensions. Res Policy 26:475–491. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(97)00025-5

Coriat B, Weinstein O (2002) Organizations, firms and institutions in the generation of innovation. Res Policy 31:273–290. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00141-X

Corsi C, Prencipe A (2019) High-tech entrepreneurial firms’ innovation in different institutional settings. Do venture capital and private equity have complementary or substitute effects? Ind Innov 26:1023–1074. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2018.1561358

Corsini F, Rizzi F, Frey M (2018) Institutional legitimacy of non-profit innovation facilitators: strategic postures in regulated environments. Technol Soc 53:69–78. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2018.01.002

Costa-Font J, Puig-Junoy J (2007) Institutional change, innovation and regulation failure: evidence from the Spanish drug market. Policy Polit 35:701–718. https://doi.org/10.1332/030557307782452994

Costa RMD, Horn CH (2021) The co-evolution of technology and employment relations: Institutions, innovation and change. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 58:313–324. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2021.06.003

Cowden BJ, Bendickson JS (2018) Impacts of regulatory focus and institutions on innovation. Manag Decis 56:939–954. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-11-2016-0826

d’Agostino G, Scarlato M (2019) Knowledge externalities, innovation and growth in European countries: the role of institutions. Econ Innov New Technol 28:82–99. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2018.1429536

Da Silva MAPM (2019) Open innovation and IPRs: Mutually incompatible or complementary institutions? J Innov Knowl 4:248–252. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jik.2018.03.010

Dahm R, Byrne JR, Rogers D, Wride MA (2021) How research institutions can foster innovation. BioEssays. https://doi.org/10.1002/bies.202100107

Daly S (2008) Institutional innovation in philanthropy: Community foundations in the UK. Voluntas 19:219–241. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11266-008-9067-7

Darvas P (1997) Institutional innovations in higher education in central Europe agenda for research and co-operation. Tert Educ Manag 3:119–132. https://doi.org/10.1080/13583883.1997.9966915

Davis L, North D (1970) Institutional change and American economic growth: a first step towards a theory of institutional innovation. J Econ Hist 30:131–149. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700078633

De Jong G, Woolthuis RK (2008) The institutional arrangements of innovation: antecedents and performance effects of trust in high-tech alliances. Ind Innov 15:45–67. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662710701858520

de la Mothe J (2004) The institutional governance of technology, society, and innovation. Technol Soc 26:523–536. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techsoc.2004.01.009

De Laurentis C (2006) Digital knowledge exploitation: ICT, memory institutions and innovation from cultural assets. J Technol Transf 31:77–89. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-005-5014-6

de Leeuw T, Gössling T (2016) Theorizing change revisited: An amended process model of institutional innovations and changes in institutional fields. J Clean Prod 135:435–448. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2016.06.119

De Mothe JL (1995) Research instrumentation and institutional innovation in Canada. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 7:63–77. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537329508524195

de Zubielqui GC, Jones J, Seet P-S, Lindsay N (2015) Knowledge transfer between actors in the innovation system: A study of higher education institutions (HEIS) and SMES. J Bus Ind Mark 30:436–458. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBIM-07-2013-0152

Desai DA (2009) Innovations in emerging countries: an institutional approach. Int J Technol Glob 4:350. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTG.2009.032736

Desmet K, Greif A, Parente SL (2020) Spatial competition, innovation and institutions: the Industrial Revolution and the Great Divergence. J Econ Growth. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-019-09173-3

Della MA, Lissoni F, Llerena P (2013) Institutional change and academic patenting: French universities and the Innovation Act of 1999. J Evol Econ 23:211–239. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0243-3

Didenko NI, Romashkina GF, Skripnuk DF, Kulik SV (2020) Dynamics of trust in institutions, the legitimacy of the social order, and social open innovation. J Open Innov Technol Mark Complex 6:1–24. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6040111

Dimitri C (2002) Contract evolution and institutional innovation: Marketing pacific-grown apples from 1890 to 1930. J Econ Hist 62:189–212. https://doi.org/10.1017/S002205070204408X

Dimitri C, Jaenicke EC, Effland AB (2009) Why did contracts supplant the cash market in the broiler industry? An economic analysis featuring technological innovation and institutional response. J Agric Food Ind Organ. https://doi.org/10.2202/1542-0485.1146

Doblinger C, Dowling M, Helm R (2016) An institutional perspective of public policy and network effects in the renewable energy industry: enablers or disablers of entrepreneurial behaviour and innovation? Entrep Reg Dev 28:126–156. https://doi.org/10.1080/08985626.2015.1109004

Dodgson M (2009) Asia’s national innovation systems: Institutional adaptability and rigidity in the face of global innovation challenges. Asia Pacific J Manag 26:589–609. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-008-9105-4

Doloreux D, Dionne S, Lapointe D (2007) Institutional structure and modes of governance in non-metropolitan innovation systems. Int J Entrep Innov Manag 7:405–423. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijeim.2007.012891

Domínguez-Escrig E, Mallén-Broch FF, Lapiedra-Alcamí R, Chiva-Gómez R (2019) The influence of leaders’ stewardship behavior on innovation success: the mediating effect of radical innovation. J Bus Ethics 159:849–862. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-018-3833-2

Drenth PJD (1996) Institutional innovations in higher education. Ann N Y Acad Sci 798:223–237. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1749-6632.1996.tb24866.x

Drew SAW (1995) Strategic benchmarking: innovation practices in financial institutions. Int J Bank Mark 13:4–16. https://doi.org/10.1108/02652329510075418

Durugbo CM (2020) After-sales services and aftermarket support: a systematic review, theory and future research directions. Int J Prod Res 58:1857–1892. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2019.1693655

Durugbo CM, Al-Jayyousi OR, Almahamid SM (2020a) Wisdom from Arabian Creatives: Systematic Review of Innovation Management Literature for the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) Region. Int J Innov Technol Manag 17:2030004-1–2030048. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219877020300049

Durugbo CM, Amoudi O, Al-Balushi Z, Anouze AL (2020b) Wisdom from Arabian networks: a review and theory of regional supply chain management. Prod Plan Control. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537287.2020.1796144

Ebegbulem CE (1974) Criteria for institutional innovation in teacher education. South Pacific J Teach Educ 2:28–32. https://doi.org/10.1080/0311213740020204

Edquist C (2006) Systems of innovation: perspectives and challenges. In: Fagerberg J, Mowery DC, Nelson RR (eds) The Oxford handbook of innovation. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 181–208

Edwards PN, King JL (2021) Institutions, Infrastructures, and Innovation. Computer (long Beach Calif) 54:103–109. https://doi.org/10.1109/MC.2020.3035921

Egan PJW (2013) R&D in the periphery? Foreign direct investment, innovation, and institutional quality in developing countries. Bus Polit 15:1–32. https://doi.org/10.1515/bap-2012-0038

Elle SM (2017) Understanding microfinance institutions and commercial banks’ relationships and innovations in the Cameroon financial environment. Strateg Chang 26:585–597. https://doi.org/10.1002/jsc.2170

Epstein SR (1994) Regional fairs, institutional innovation, and economic growth in late medieval Europe. Econ Hist Rev 47:459–482. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0289.1994.tb01386.x

Ervits I, Zmuda M (2018) A cross-country comparison of the effects of institutions on internationally oriented innovation. J Int Entrep 16:486–503. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10843-018-0225-8

Escobal J (2000) Endogenous institutional innovation and agroindustrialization on the Peruvian coast. Agric Econ 23:267–277. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-5150(00)00088-8

Etzkowitz H, Germain-Alamartine E, Keel J et al (2019) Entrepreneurial university dynamics: Structured ambivalence, relative deprivation and institution-formation in the Stanford innovation system. Technol Forecast Soc Change 141:159–171. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2018.10.019

Farrell KR, Runge CF (1983) Institutional innovation and technical change in american agriculture: The role of the new deal. Am J Agric Econ 65:1168–1173. https://doi.org/10.2307/1240442

Ferderer JP (2003) Institutional innovation and the creation of liquid financial markets: the case of bankers’ acceptances, 1914–1934. J Econ Hist 63:666–694. https://doi.org/10.1017/S002205070354195X

Ferguson J-PJ-P, Carnabuci G (2017) Risky recombinations: institutional gatekeeping in the innovation process. Organ Sci 28:133–151. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2016.1106

Filiou D, Golesorkhi S (2016) Influence of institutional differences on firm innovation from international alliances. Long Range Plann 49:129–144. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2014.09.005

Fischer B, Tello-Gamarra J (2017) Institutional quality as a driver of efficiency in laggard innovation systems. J Glob Compet Governability 11:129–144. https://doi.org/10.3232/GCG.2017.V11.N1.06

Foray D, Woerter M (2021) The formation of Coasean institutions to provide university knowledge for innovation: a case study and econometric evidence for Switzerland. J Technol Transf 46:1584–1610. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-020-09828-z

Forde C (2020) Participatory governance in Ireland: Institutional innovation and the quest for joined-up thinking. Administration 68:1–20. https://doi.org/10.2478/admin-2020-0013

Frey BS, Lüthi R, Osterloh M (2012) Community enterprises-an institutional innovation. Manag Decis Econ 33:427–439. https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2556

Fritsch M, Schwirten C (1999) Enterprise-university co-operation and the role of public research institutions in regional innovation systems. Ind Innov 6:69–83. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662719900000005

Fritsch S (2015) Technological innovation, globalization, and varieties of capitalism: the case of Siemens AG as example for contingent institutional adaptation. Bus Polit 17:125–159. https://doi.org/10.1515/bap-2014-0020

Fuentelsaz L, Maicas JP, Montero J (2018) Entrepreneurs and innovation: the contingent role of institutional factors. Int Small Bus J Res Entrep 36:686–711. https://doi.org/10.1177/0266242618766235

Fullerton RA (1986) Understanding institutional innovation and system evolution in distribution. the contribution of Robert Nieschlag. Int J Res Mark 3:273–282. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-8116(86)90007-8

Fumasoli T, Rossi F (2021) The role of higher education institutions in transnational networks for teaching and learning innovation: the case of the Erasmus+ programme. Eur J Educ 56:200–218. https://doi.org/10.1111/ejed.12454

Fung A (2012) Continuous institutional innovation and the pragmatic conception of democracy. Polity 44:609–624. https://doi.org/10.1057/pol.2012.17

Gachie W (2020) Higher education institutions, private sector and government collaboration for innovation within the framework of the Triple Helix Model. African J Sci Technol Innov Dev 12:203–215. https://doi.org/10.1080/20421338.2019.1631120

Galindo-Martín M-A, Méndez-Picazo M-T, Castaño-Martínez M-S (2020) The role of innovation and institutions in entrepreneurship and economic growth in two groups of countries. Int J Entrep Behav Res 26:485–502. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJEBR-06-2019-0336

Gallery N, Gordon EA (2008) Sustainability in global financial reporting and innovation in institutions. Account Res J 21:231–238. https://doi.org/10.1108/10309610810922486

Gande A, John K, Nair VB, Senbet LW (2020) Taxes, institutions, and innovation: theory and international evidence. J Int Bus Stud 51:1413–1442. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-020-00375-1

Gao X, Zhai K, Qiu Y et al (2020) Innovation institution and spatial transfer of energy industry: the case of Jiangsu Province. China SAGE Open. https://doi.org/10.1177/2158244019900181

Gao Y, Gao S, Zhou Y, Huang K-F (2015) Picturing firms’ institutional capital-based radical innovation under China’s institutional voids. J Bus Res 68:1166–1175. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.11.011

Gao Y, Shu C, Jiang X et al (2017) Managerial ties and product innovation: the moderating roles of macro- and micro-institutional environments. Long Range Plann 50:168–183. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2016.11.005

García JS, Velásquez JR (2013) Methodology for evaluating Innovation Capabilities at university institutions using a fuzzy system. J Technol Manag Innov 8:246–259. https://doi.org/10.4067/s0718-27242013000300051

Garrick D, Lane-Miller C, McCoy AL (2011) Institutional innovations to govern environmental water in the Western United States: lessons for Australia’s Murray-Darling Basin. Econ Pap A J Appl Econ Policy 30:167–184. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1759-3441.2011.00104.x

Garrone P, Grilli L, Mrkajic B (2018) The role of institutional pressures in the introduction of energy-efficiency innovations. Bus Strateg Environ 27:1245–1257. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.2072

Geels FW (2004) From sectoral systems of innovation to socio-technical systems: Insights about dynamics and change from sociology and institutional theory. Res Policy 33:897–920. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2004.01.015

Gehman J, Höllerer MA (2019) Venturing into the cultural future: research opportunities at the nexus of institutions, innovation and impact. Innov Manag Policy Pract 21:229–248. https://doi.org/10.1080/14479338.2018.1552520

Genus A (2012) Changing the rules? Institutional innovation and the diffusion of microgeneration. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 24:711–727. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2012.705122

George G, Prabhu GN (2003) Developmental financial institutions as technology policy instruments: implications for innovation and entrepreneurship in emerging economies. Res Policy 32:89–108. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(02)00002-1

Gittelman M (2006) National institutions, public-private knowledge flows, and innovation performance: a comparative study of the biotechnology industry in the US and France. Res Policy 35:1052–1068. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2006.05.005

Godden D (1991) Induced institutional innovation: Plant variety rights, patents and genetic engineering. Oxford Agrar Stud 19:3–19. https://doi.org/10.1080/13600819108424032

Godlewska M (2021) The impact of interplay between formal and informal institutions on innovation performance: Evidence from ceecs. Eng Econ 32:15–26. https://doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.32.1.27390

Goldsmith AA (1988) The management of institutional innovation: Lessons from transferring the land grant model to India. Public Adm Dev 8:317–330. https://doi.org/10.1002/pad.4230080306

Gongbuzeren ZJ, Zhuang M et al (2021) Mitigating the impacts of fragmented land tenure through community-based institutional innovations: Two case study villages from Guinan County of Qinghai Province. China Ecol Soc. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-12326-260215

González-López M (2011) The institutions-innovation dilemma: the case of coastal fisheries. J Technol Manag Innov 6:184–195. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-27242011000300014

Grabowski R (1991) Agricultural development and institutional innovation: a view of early Japan. J Asian Econ 2:249–263. https://doi.org/10.1016/1049-0078(91)90038-M

Grabowski R (1988) The theory of induced institutional innovation: a critique. World Dev 16:385–394. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(88)90005-8

Gretchenko AI, Nikitskaya EF, Valishvili MA, Gretchenko AA (2018) Role of higher education institutions in developing hr potential in a forming innovation economy. Espacios 39(21):13

Gupta AK, Sinha R, Koradia D et al (2003) Mobilizing grassroots’ technological innovations and traditional knowledge, values and institutions: articulating social and ethical capital. Futures 35:975–987. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0016-3287(03)00053-3

Hage J, Hollingsworth JR (2000) A strategy for the analysis of idea innovation networks and institutions. Organ Stud 21:971–1004. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840600215006

Hagel J, Brown JS (2013) Institutional innovation: Creating smarter organizations to scale learning. Deloitte Center Edge 12(5):1–22

Haggard S, Zheng Y (2013) Institutional innovation and investment in Taiwan: the micro-foundations of the developmental state. Bus Polit 15:435–466. https://doi.org/10.1515/bap-2012-0010

Halpern C (2005) Institutional change through innovation: The URBAN Community Initiative in Berlin, 1994–99. Environ Plan C Gov Policy 23:697–713. https://doi.org/10.1068/c0416

Hamdouch A, Moulaert F (2006) Knowledge infrastructure, innovation dynamics, and knowledge creation/diffusion/accumulation processes: a comparative institutional perspective. Innovation 19:25–50. https://doi.org/10.1080/13511610600607676

Hao Z, Yunlong D (2014) Research on the relationship of institutional innovation, organizational learning and synergistic effect: An empirical study of Chinese university spin-offs. J Ind Eng Manag 7:645–659. https://doi.org/10.3926/jiem.950

Harding R (2000) Resilience in German technology policy: innovation through institutional symbiotic tension. Ind Innov 7:223–243. https://doi.org/10.1080/713670251

Hargadon AB, Douglas Y (2001) When innovations meet institutions: edison and the design of the electric light. Adm Sci Q 46:476–501. https://doi.org/10.2307/3094872

Hargrave TJ, Van De Ven AH (2006) A collective action model of institutional innovation. Acad Manag Rev 31:864–888. https://doi.org/10.5465/AMR.2006.22527458

Hart DM (2001) Antitrust and technological innovation in the US: ideas, institutions, decisions, and impacts, 1890–2000. Res Policy 30:923–936. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(00)00165-7

Heher AD (2006) Return on investment in innovation: Implications for institutions and national agencies. J Technol Transf 31:403–414. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-006-0002-z

Helleiner E, Wang H (2018) Limits to the BRICS’ challenge: credit rating reform and institutional innovation in global finance. Rev Int Polit Econ 25:573–595. https://doi.org/10.1080/09692290.2018.1490330

Hernández V, Nieto MJ, Rodríguez A (2021) Home country institutions and exports of firms in transition economies: Does innovation matter? Long Range Plann. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2021.102087

Hinings B, Gegenhuber T, Greenwood R (2018) Digital innovation and transformation: an institutional perspective. Inf Organ 28:52–61. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoandorg.2018.02.004

Holloway G (2000) Agroindustrialization through institutional innovation transaction costs, cooperatives and milk-market development in the east-African highlands. Agric Econ 23:279–288. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-5150(00)00089-X

Hoque M, Chishty M, Halloway R (2011) Commercialization and changes in capital structure in microfinance institutions: An innovation or wrong turn? Manag Financ 37:414–425. https://doi.org/10.1108/03074351111126906

Hoskisson RE, Hitt MA, Johnson RA, Grossman W (2002) Conflicting voices: the effects of institutional ownership heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation strategies. Acad Manag J 45:697–716. https://doi.org/10.2307/3069305

Hou B, Hong J, Chen Q et al (2019) Do academia-industry R&D collaborations necessarily facilitate industrial innovation in China?: The role of technology transfer institutions. Eur J Innov Manag 22:717–746. https://doi.org/10.1108/EJIM-09-2018-0195

Hou J, Chan EHW, Li LH (2018) Transfer of development rights as an institutional innovation to address issues of property rights. J Hous Built Environ 33:465–479. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10901-018-9613-6

Hsu C, Lee J-N, Straub DW (2012) Institutional influences on information systems security innovations. Inf Syst Res 23:918–939. https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.1110.0393

Hu K (2014) The institutional innovation of the lender of last resort facility in the eurozone. J Eur Integr 36:627–640. https://doi.org/10.1080/07036337.2014.913039

Huang J, Ding J (2016) Institutional innovation and policy support to facilitate small-scale farming transformation in China. Agric Econ 47:227–237. https://doi.org/10.1111/agec.12309

Huang KG-LKG-L, Geng X, Wang H (2017) Institutional regime shift in intellectual property rights and innovation strategies of firms in China. Organ Sci 28:355–377. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.2017.1117

Huang Y-C, Yang M-L (2014) Reverse logistics innovation, institutional pressures and performance. Manag Res Rev 37:615–641. https://doi.org/10.1108/MRR-03-2013-0069

Huber-Stearns HR, Schultz C, Cheng AS (2019) A multiple streams analysis of institutional innovation in forest watershed governance. Rev Policy Res 36:781–804. https://doi.org/10.1111/ropr.12359

Hueske A-K, Guenther E (2015) What hampers innovation? External stakeholders, the organization, groups and individuals: a systematic review of empirical barrier research. Manag Rev Q 65:113–148. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11301-014-0109-5

Hug S (2005) The political effects of referendums: An analysis of institutional innovations in Eastern and Central Europe. Communist Post-Communist Stud 38:475–499. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.postcomstud.2005.09.006

Hughes I, Byrne E, Glatz-Schmallegger M et al (2021) Deep institutional innovation for sustainability and human development. World Futures 77:371–394. https://doi.org/10.1080/02604027.2021.1929013

Hull A (1996) Strategic plan-making in Europe: institutional innovation. Plan Pract Res 11:253–264. https://doi.org/10.1080/02697459616834

Hung S-C (2000) Institutions and systems of innovation: an empirical analysis of Taiwan’s personal computer competitiveness. Technol Soc 22:175–187. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0160-791X(00)00005-1

Hung S-CS-CS-C, Whittington R (2011) Agency in national innovation systems: Institutional entrepreneurship and the professionalization of Taiwanese IT. Res Policy 40:526–538. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.01.008

Hüsig S, Mann H-G (2010) The role of promoters in effecting innovation in higher education institutions. Innov Manag Policy Pract 12:180–191. https://doi.org/10.5172/impp.12.2.180

Hussen MS, Çokgezen M (2021) Relationship between innovation, regional institutions and firm performance: Micro-evidence from Africa. African J Sci Technol Innov Dev. https://doi.org/10.1080/20421338.2020.1866148

Huston S, Rahimzad R, Parsa A (2015) “Smart” sustainable urban regeneration: institutions, quality and financial innovation. Cities 48:66–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2015.05.005

Hyvärinen J (2006) EU enlargement, institutional governance and innovation environment in the Baltic countries. J East-West Bus 12:39–70. https://doi.org/10.1300/J097v12n04_03

Iqbal A (2021) Innovation speed and quality in higher education institutions: the role of knowledge management enablers and knowledge sharing process. J Knowl Manag. https://doi.org/10.1108/JKM-07-2020-0546

Irlenbusch B, Leopold-Wildburger U, Schütze J, Sutter M (2003) Voting in EMU—an experimental study of institutional innovation and the role of communication in the stability and growth pact. JCMS J Common Mark Stud 41:645–664. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-5965.00439

Ito J, Bao Z, Ni J (2016) Land rental development via institutional innovation in rural Jiangsu, China. Food Policy 59:1–11. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2015.12.005

Janssen MA, Ostrom E (2008) TURFS in the lab: institutional innovation in real-time dynamic spatial commons. Ration Soc 20:371–397. https://doi.org/10.1177/1043463108096786

Jansson F, Lindenfors P, Sandberg M (2013) Democratic revolutions as institutional innovation diffusion: Rapid adoption and survival of democracy. Technol Forecast Soc Change 80:1546–1556. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2013.02.002

Jayabalan J, Dorasamy M, Raman M (2021) Reshaping higher educational institutions through frugal open innovation. J Open Innov Technol Mark Complex. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc7020145

Jensen PH, Fersch B (2019) Institutional entrepreneurs and social innovation in danish senior care. Adm Soc 51:250–271. https://doi.org/10.1177/0095399715624945

Jiang X, Yuan Q (2018) Institutional investors’ corporate site visits and corporate innovation. J Corp Financ 48:148–168. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2017.09.019

Jiang X, Zhang P (2020) Institutions, policies and diverse innovation systems: experiences from the US, Germany and South Korea. J Asian Public Policy 13:241–255. https://doi.org/10.1080/17516234.2018.1541116

Johannessen J (2008) Explaining institutional change: aspects of an innovation in the new institutional economy. Kybernetes 37:20–35. https://doi.org/10.1108/03684920810850961

Jucevicius G, Juceviciene R, Gaidelys V, Kalman A (2016) The emerging innovation ecosystems and “Valley of death”: Towards the combination of entrepreneurial and institutional approaches. Eng Econ 27:430–438. https://doi.org/10.5755/j01.ee.27.4.14403

Juk YV, Fuck MP (2015) Innovations and support institutions: The 1st geographical indication in Brazil. J Technol Manag Innov 10:117–126. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-27242015000200008

Jun K-NK-NK-NK-N, Weare C (2011) Institutional motivations in the adoption of innovations: the case of e-government. J Public Adm Res Theory 21:495–519. https://doi.org/10.1093/jopart/muq020

Jun Q, Dinçer H, Yüksel S (2021) Stochastic hybrid decision-making based on interval type 2 fuzzy sets for measuring the innovation capacities of financial institutions. Int J Financ Econ 26:573–593. https://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1805

Kadriu A, Krasniqi BA, Boari C (2019) The impact of institutions on SMEs’ innovation in transition economies. Int J Entrep Innov Manag 23:399–424. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJEIM.2019.100804

Kafouros M, Wang C, Piperopoulos P, Zhang M (2015) Academic collaborations and firm innovation performance in China: the role of region-specific institutions. Res Policy 44:803–817. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2014.11.002

Kalinowski T (2020) Institutional innovations and their challenges in the green climate fund: country ownership, civil society participation and private sector engagement. Sustain 12:1–13. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12218827

Kalkabayeva G, Rakhmetova A, Doskaliyeva B et al (2021) The investments of financial institutions in real innovations: Kazakhstani practice. Intellect Econ 15:104–115. https://doi.org/10.13165/IE-21-15-1-07

Kang Y, He X (2018) Institutional forces and environmental management strategy: moderating effects of environmental orientation and innovation capability. Manag Organ Rev 14:577–605. https://doi.org/10.1017/mor.2017.56

Kang Y, Jiang J (2020) Revisiting the innovation systems of cross-border cities: the role of higher education institution and cross-boundary cooperation in Hong Kong and Shenzhen. J High Educ Policy Manag 42:213–229. https://doi.org/10.1080/1360080X.2019.1701849

Kapetaniou C, Samdanis M, Lee SH (2018) Innovation policies of cyprus during the global economic crisis: aligning financial institutions with national innovation system. Technol Forecast Soc Change 133:29–40. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2018.02.019

Karaulova M, Shackleton O, Liu W et al (2017) Institutional change and innovation system transformation: A tale of two academies. Technol Forecast Soc Change 116:196–207. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.10.018

Kasper W (1994) Institutional innovation and the calculus of world competitiveness. Econ Anal Policy 24:37–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0313-5926(94)50003-1

Kasperavičiūtė-Černiauskienė R, Serafinas D (2018) The adoption of ISO 9001 standard within higher education institutions in lithuania: Innovation diffusion approach. Total Qual Manag Bus Excell 29:74–93. https://doi.org/10.1080/14783363.2016.1164012

Kawabata MK, Camargo Junior AS (2020) Innovation and institutions’ quality: a comparative study between countries. Int J Innov Sci 12:169–185. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJIS-10-2019-0100

Khan A, Gulati R (2021) Productivity growth, catching-up and technology innovation in microfinance institutions in India: evidence using a bootstrap Malmquist Index approach. Benchmarking Int J Ahead-of-P. https://doi.org/10.1108/BIJ-10-2020-0535

Khan KS, Kunz R, Kleijnen J, Antes G (2003) Systematic reviews to support evidence-based medicine: how to review and apply findings of healthcare research. Royal Society of Medicine Press, London

Kidd RM (1996) Institutional innovations: the maine science and technology foundation as a public-private partnership for science-based economic growth. Ann N Y Acad Sci 798:123–126. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1749-6632.1996.tb24860.x

Kikuchi M, Hayami Y (1983) New rice technology, intrarural migration, and institutional innovation in the Philippines. Popul Dev Rev 9:247. https://doi.org/10.2307/1973051

Kim H, Park K, Roy Song K (2019) Do long-term institutional investors foster corporate innovation? Account Financ 59:1163–1195. https://doi.org/10.1111/acfi.12284

King JL, Gurbaxani V, Kraemer KL et al (1994) Institutional factors in information technology innovation. Inf Syst Res 5:139–169. https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.5.2.139

Kitagawa F, Robertson S (2011) City-regions, innovation challenges and universities: New shifts in the UK urban governance institutions. Int J Knowledge-Based Dev 2:185–201. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJKBD.2011.041247

Kitchenham B, Charters S (2007) Guidelines for performing systematic literature reviews in software engineering

Knickel M, Neuberger S, Klerkx L et al (2021) Strengthening the role of academic institutions and innovation brokers in agri-food innovation: Towards hybridisation in cross-border cooperation. Sustain. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13094899

Kochhar R, David P (1996) Institutional investors and firm innovation: a test of competing hypotheses. Strateg Manag J 17:73–84. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1097-0266(199601)17:1%3c73::AID-SMJ795%3e3.3.CO;2-E

Koh WTH (2006) Singapore’s transition to innovation-based economic growth: infrastructure, institutions and government’s role. R D Manag 36:143–160. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9310.2006.00422.x

Kolk A, Lenfant F (2015) Cross-sector collaboration, institutional gaps, and fragility: the role of social innovation partnerships in a conflict-affected region. J Public Policy Mark 34:287–303. https://doi.org/10.1509/jppm.14.157

Kooijman M, Hekkert MP, van Meer PJK et al (2017) How institutional logics hamper innovation: the case of animal testing. Technol Forecast Soc Change 118:70–79. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.02.003

Kraft PS, Bausch A (2018) Managerial social networks and innovation: a meta-analysis of bonding and bridging effects across institutional environments. J Prod Innov Manag 35:865–889. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12450

Krech M (2020) Towards equal rights in the global game? FIFA’s strategy for women’s football as a tightly bounded institutional innovation. Tilbg Law Rev 25:12–26. https://doi.org/10.5334/TILR.190

Krishnan RT, Jha SK (2012) Innovation in the Indian automotive industry: the role of academic and public research institutions. Asian J Technol Innov 20:67–84. https://doi.org/10.1080/19761597.2012.683945

Kruss G (2005) Harnessing innovation potential?: Institutional approaches to industry-higher education research partnerships in South Africa. Ind High Educ 19:131–142. https://doi.org/10.5367/0000000053729806

Kukk P, Moors EHM, Hekkert MP (2016) Institutional power play in innovation systems: the case of Herceptin®. Res Policy 45:1558–1569. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.01.016

Kumar V, Mudambi R, Gray S (2013) Internationalization, innovation and institutions: the 3 I’s underpinning the competitiveness of emerging market firms. J Int Manag 19:203–206. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2013.03.005

Kumari R, Kwon K-S, Lee B-H, Choi K (2020) Co-creation for social innovation in the ecosystem context: the role of higher educational institutions. Sustain 12:1–21. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12010307

Kunamaneni S (2019) Challenges in moving from incremental to radical low-cost innovation in emerging and transition countries : institutional perspectives based on rechargeable battery innovation in China and point-of-use water purification innovation in India. Int J Innov Manag 23:1950028. https://doi.org/10.1142/S1363919619500282

Kwan LY-Y, Chiu C (2015) Country variations in different innovation outputs: the interactive effect of institutional support and human capital. J Organ Behav 36:1050–1070. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.2017

Kwon M, Berry FS, Feiock RC (2009) Understanding the adoption and timing of economic development strategies in US cities using innovation and institutional analysis. J Public Adm Res Theory 19:967–988. https://doi.org/10.1093/jopart/mun026

Kwon S, Motohashi K (2017) How institutional arrangements in the national innovation system affect industrial competitiveness: a study of Japan and the U.S. with multiagent simulation. Technol Forecast Soc Change 115:221–235. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.10.005

la Hiz DI, Hurtado-Torres N, Bermúdez-Edo M (2019) The heterogeneity of levels of green innovation by firms in international contexts: a study based on the home-country institutional profile. Organ Environ 32:508–527. https://doi.org/10.1177/1086026618761623

Landoni M (2017) Innovation policy in progress. Institutional intermediation in public procurement of innovation: satellite telecommunications in Italy. R D Manag 47:583–594. https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12246

Lane J-E (1986) Institutional innovation and implementation: the case of Sweden. Policy Stud J 14:470–477. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-0072.1986.tb00746.x

Larsen K, Gunnarsson-Östling U, Westholm E (2011) Environmental scenarios and local-global level of community engagement: environmental justice, jams, institutions and innovation. Futures 43:413–423. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.futures.2011.01.007

Laurell H (2018) An international new venture’s commercialization of a medical technology innovation: the role of institutional healthcare settings. Int Mark Rev 35:136–163. https://doi.org/10.1108/IMR-04-2015-0112

Lauto G, Bau M, Compagno C (2013) Individual and Institutional Drivers of Technology Transfer in Open Innovation. Ind High Educ 27:27–39. https://doi.org/10.5367/ihe.2013.0136

Lazer D, Mergel I, Ziniel C et al (2011) The Multiple Institutional Logics of Innovation. Int Public Manag J 14:311–340. https://doi.org/10.1080/10967494.2011.618308

Lee K-JK-J (2012) The coevolution of IT innovation and copyright institutions: the development of the mobile music business in Japan and Korea. J Strateg Inf Syst 21:245–255. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jsis.2012.04.001

Lee SH, Yoo T (2008) Competing rationales for corporate governance in France: Institutional complementarities between financial markets and innovation systems. Corp Gov an Int Rev 16:63–76. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2008.00669.x

Lee WC, Law SH (2017) Roles of formal institutions and social capital in innovation activities: a cross-country analysis. Glob Econ Rev 46:203–231. https://doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2017.1292859

Léopold M, Thébaud O, Charles A (2019) The dynamics of institutional innovation: crafting co-management in small-scale fisheries through action research. J Environ Manage 237:187–199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2019.01.112

Levien RE (1971) Institutions, innovation, and incentives. IEEE Trans Educ 14:148–153. https://doi.org/10.1109/TE.1971.4320689

Li H, Sheng Y, Yan X (2020) Empirical research on the level of institutional innovation in the development of China’s high-tech industry. IEEE Access 8:115800–115811. https://doi.org/10.1109/ACCESS.2020.3003932

Li J, Leeuwis C, Van BETL et al (2012) Contribution of action researching to institutional innovation: a case study of access and benefit sharing (ABS) mechanisms in the participatory plant breeding (PPB) in Southwest China. Int J Agric Resour Gov Ecol 9:204. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJARGE.2012.050349

Li J, Xing J (2020) Why Is collaborative agglomeration of innovation so important for improving regional innovation capabilities? A perspective based on collaborative agglomeration of industry-university-research institution. Complexity. https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/7049606

Li X (2015) Specialization, institutions and innovation within China’s regional innovation systems. Technol Forecast Soc Change 100:130–139. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2015.06.032

Liao Z (2018) Institutional pressure, knowledge acquisition and a firm’s environmental innovation. Bus Strateg Environ 27:849–857. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.2036

Lin JY (1995) Endowments, technology, and factor markets: a natural experiment of induced institutional innovation from China’s rural reform. Am J Agric Econ 77:231–242. https://doi.org/10.2307/1243533

Lindelöf P (2011) Formal institutional contexts as ownership of intellectual property rights and their implications for the organization of commercialization of innovations at universities comparative data from Sweden and the United Kingdom. Int J Innov Manag 15:1069–1092. https://doi.org/10.1142/S1363919611003611

Lisowska R, Stanisławski R (2014) Institutional support system for the development of SME innovation. Int J Innov Learn 16:319–337. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJIL.2014.064734

Liu FF-CF, Simon DF, Sun Y, Cao C (2011) China’s innovation policies: Evolution, institutional structure, and trajectory. Res Policy 40:917–931. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2011.05.005

Liu J (2016) Regional institutions and their impact on the connectedness of firm’s innovation networks. Institutions Econ 8:102–129

Llopis O, D’Este P (2016) Beneficiary contact and innovation: The relation between contact with patients and medical innovation under different institutional logics. Res Policy 45:1512–1523. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.03.004

Lobe K, Berkes F (2004) The padu system of community-based fisheries management: change and local institutional innovation in south India. Mar Policy 28:271–281. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0308-597X(03)00087-3

Lounsbury M, Crumley ET (2007) New practice creation: an institutional perspective on innovation: Michael Lounsbury and Ellen T. Crumley Organ Stud 28:993–1012. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840607078111

Lui AKH, Ngai EWT, Lo CKY (2016) Disruptive information technology innovations and the cost of equity capital: The moderating effect of CEO incentives and institutional pressures. Inf Manag 53:345–354. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.im.2015.09.009

Lund HB, Karlsen A (2020) The importance of vocational education institutions in manufacturing regions: adding content to a broad definition of regional innovation systems. Ind Innov 27:660–679. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2019.1616534

Lynn LH, Reddy NM, Aram JD (1996) Linking technology and institutions: the innovation community framework. Res Policy 25:91–106. https://doi.org/10.1016/0048-7333(94)00817-5

Lyu L, Wu W, Hu H, Huang R (2019) An evolving regional innovation network: collaboration among industry, university, and research institution in China’s first technology hub. J Technol Transf 44:659–680. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-017-9620-x

Ma X-F, Kaldenbach M, Katzy B (2014) Cross-border innovation intermediaries - matchmaking across institutional contexts. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 26:703–716. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2014.899346

Ma Z, Yu M, Gao C et al (2015) Institutional constraints of product innovation in China: evidence from international joint ventures. J Bus Res 68:949–956. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.09.022

Magalhães CS (2004) Centres of excellence for urban regeneration: promoting institutional capacity and innovation or reaffirming old ideas? Plan Theory Pract 5:33–47. https://doi.org/10.1080/1464935042000185053

Magnier-Watanabe R, Senoo D (2009) The effect of institutional pressures on knowledge management and the resulting innovation: the case of the smartcard in France. Int J Intell Enterp 1:177–197. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJIE.2009.024410

Maksimov V, Wang SL, Luo Y (2017) Institutional imprinting, entrepreneurial agency, and private firm innovation in transition economies. J World Bus 52:854–865. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2017.06.002

Malen J, Vaaler PM (2017) Organizational slack, national institutions and innovation effort around the world. J World Bus 52:782–797. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2017.07.001

Mandal MAS (1987) Imperfect institutional innovation for irrigation management in Bangladesh. Irrig Drain Syst 1:239–258. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01102933

Markey-Towler B (2020) Blockchains and institutional competition in innovation systems. J Entrep Public Policy 9:185–193. https://doi.org/10.1108/JEPP-03-2019-0015

Martin G, Siebert S, Robson I (2018) Conformist innovation: an institutional logics perspective on how HR executives construct business school reputations. Int J Hum Resour Manag 29:2027–2053. https://doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2016.1239118

Martin MJC (1994) Managing innovation and entrepreneurship in technology-based firms. Wiley, New York

Martínez-Pérez Á, Elche D, García-Villaverde PM, Parra-Requena G (2019) Cultural tourism clusters: social capital, relations with institutions, and radical innovation. J Travel Res 58:793–807. https://doi.org/10.1177/0047287518778147

Mason G, Wagner K (1999) Knowledge transfer and innovation in Germany and Britain: “Intermediate institution” models of knowledge transfer under strain? Ind Innov 6:85–109. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662719900000006

Matzner E (1985) Technological and institutional innovation. Ann Public Coop Econ 56:71–80. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8292.1985.tb01980.x

May C, Schedelik M (2019) Comparative capitalism and innovation policy: complementarities and comparative institutional advantage. J Econ Policy Reform. https://doi.org/10.1080/17487870.2019.1637589

May PH (2008) Overcoming contradictions between growth and sustainability: institutional innovation in the BRICS. Chinese J Popul Resour Environ 6:3–13. https://doi.org/10.1080/10042857.2008.10684876

McCann L (2004) Induced institutional innovation and transaction costs: the case of the Australian National native title Tribunal. Rev Soc Econ 62:67–82. https://doi.org/10.1080/0034676042000183835

McCarthy DJ, Puffer SM, Graham LR, Satinsky DM (2014) Emerging innovation in emerging economies: Can institutional reforms help Russia break through its historical barriers? Thunderbird Int Bus Rev 56:243–260. https://doi.org/10.1002/tie.21619

Mehmood A (2016) Institutional forms of social innovation. Int J Innov Sustain Dev 10:300–311. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJISD.2016.077512

Menzies J (2013) Reducing tensions in Australian intergovernmental relations through institutional innovation. Aust J Public Adm 72:382–389. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8500.12036

Mia MA (2020) Technological change and innovations in microfinance institutions: what matters? Glob Bus Rev. https://doi.org/10.1177/0972150920927368

Minh TT, Hjortsø CN (2015) How institutions influence SME innovation and networking practices: the case of vietnamese agribusiness. J Small Bus Manag 53:209–228. https://doi.org/10.1111/jsbm.12189

Mishchenko S, Naumenkova S, Mishchenko V, Dorofeiev D (2021) Innovation risk management in financial institutions. Invest Manag Financ Innov 18:191–203. https://doi.org/10.21511/imfi.18(1).2021.16

Mohsen K, Saeed S, Raza A et al (2021) Does using latest technologies impact new venture innovation? A contingency-based view of institutional environments. J Small Bus Manag 59:852–886. https://doi.org/10.1111/jsbm.12534

Molina-Morales FX, Mas-Verdu F (2008) Intended ties with local institutions as factors in innovation: an application to spanish manufacturing firms. Eur Plan Stud 16:811–827. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654310802079452

Molnár I (2004) Legal and institutional aspects of the innovation system of the European integration. Period Polytech Soc Manag Sci 12:103–122

Monteiro S, Isusi-Fagoaga R, Almeida L, García-Aracil A (2021) Contribution of higher education institutions to social innovation: Practices in two southern european universities. Sustain. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13073594

Moon H, Mariadoss BJ, Johnson JL (2019) Collaboration with higher education institutions for successful firm innovation. J Bus Res 99:534–541. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2017.09.033

Moore G (2011) Institutional Innovation: re-invigorating the university through transdisciplinary engagement. Triplec Commun Capital Crit Open Access J Glob Sustain Inf Soc 9:598–609. https://doi.org/10.31269/triplec.v9i2.198

Mosconi F, D’Ingiullo D (2021) Institutional quality and innovation: evidence from Emilia-Romagna. Econ Innov New Technol. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2021.1893140

Mueller V, Rosenbusch N, Bausch A (2013) Success patterns of exploratory and exploitative innovation: a meta-analysis of the influence of institutional factors. J Manage 39:1606–1636. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206313484516

Munene JC (1995) The institutional environment and managerial innovations: a qualitative study of selected Nigerian firms. J Occup Organ Psychol 68:291–300. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8325.1995.tb00588.x

Mutenje M, Kankwamba H, Mangisonib J, Kassie M (2016) Agricultural innovations and food security in Malawi: Gender dynamics, institutions and market implications. Technol Forecast Soc Change 103:240–248. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2015.10.004

Na LJ, Ofori G, Ling FYY, Hua GB (2007) Role of national institutions in promoting innovation by contractors in Singapore. Constr Manag Econ 25:1021–1039. https://doi.org/10.1080/01446190701209925

Nagamatsu A, Watanabe C, Shum KL (2006) Diffusion trajectory of self-propagating innovations interacting with institutions—incorporation of multi-factors learning function to model PV diffusion in Japan. Energy Policy 34:411–421. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2004.06.010

Nakamura L, Born SM (1993) Substate institutional innovation for managing lakes and watersheds: a Wisconsin case study. J Am Water Resour Assoc 29:807–821. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1752-1688.1993.tb03240.x

Nam D-IDD-I, Parboteeah KP, Cullen JB, Johnson JL (2014) Cross-national differences in firms undertaking innovation initiatives: an application of institutional anomie theory. J Int Manag 20:91–106. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2013.05.001

Nelson RR, Nelson K (2002) Technology, institutions, and innovation systems. Res Policy 31:265–272. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00140-8

Nielsen JR, Degnbol P, Viswanathan KK et al (2004) Fisheries co-management—an institutional innovation? Lessons from South East Asia and Southern Africa. Mar Policy 28:151–160. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0308-597X(03)00083-6

Nieto M, González-Álvarez N (2014) Product innovation: testing the relative influence of industry, institutional context and firm factors. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 26:1023–1036. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2014.944146

Nikolaou IE, Evangelinos KI, Leal Filho W (2010) Intellectual property and environmental innovation: an explanation using the institutional and resource-based theories. Int J Foresight Innov Policy 6:268–281. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJFIP.2010.037472

Niosi J (2010) Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries. Innov Manag Policy Pract 12:250–268. https://doi.org/10.5172/impp.12.3.250

Nite C, Washington M (2017) Institutional adaptation to technological innovation: Lessons from the NCAA’s regulation of football television broadcasts (1938–1984). J Sport Manag 31:575–590. https://doi.org/10.1123/jsm.2017-0159

Nkundabanyanga SK, Mugumya E, Nalukenge I et al (2020) Firm characteristics, innovation, financial resilience and survival of financial institutions. J Acc Emerg Econ 10:48–73. https://doi.org/10.1108/JAEE-08-2018-0094

Nolan P, Xiaoqiang W (1999) Beyond privatization: Institutional innovation and growth in China’s large state-owned enterprises. World Dev 27:169–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(98)00132-6

Nooteboom B (2000) Institutions and forms of co-ordination in innovation systems. Organ Stud 21:915–939. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840600215004

Nordberg M, Campbell A, Verbeke A (2003) Using customer relationships to acquire technological innovation. A value-chain analysis of supplier contracts with scientific research institutions. J Bus Res 56:711–719. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0148-2963(01)00256-9

North DC (1991) Institutions. J Econ Perspect 5:97–112. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.5.1.97

North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Nyseth T, Ventura López TD (2021) Innovations in urban integration policies: immigrant councils as democratic institutions. Cities. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cities.2021.103389

Oborn E, Pilosof NP, Hinings B, Zimlichman E (2021) Institutional logics and innovation in times of crisis: telemedicine as digital ‘PPE.’ Inf Organ 31:100340. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoandorg.2021.100340

OECD/Eurostat (2018) Oslo Manual 2018: Guidelines for Collecting, Reporting and Using Data on Innovation, 4th Edition, The Measurement of Scientific, Technological and Innovation Activities. OECD Publishing, Paris

Oi WY (2004) The supermarket: an institutional innovation. Aust Econ Rev 37:337–342. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8462.2004.00335.x

Onsongo E (2019) Institutional entrepreneurship and social innovation at the base of the pyramid: the case of M-Pesa in Kenya. Ind Innov 26:369–390. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2017.1409104

Oppong N (2016) The twists and turns of institutional innovation in small island developing states: the case of Tuvalu. Commonw Comp Polit 54:23–45. https://doi.org/10.1080/14662043.2015.1124498

Oppong N, Andrews N (2020) Extractive industries transparency initiative and the politics of institutional innovation in Ghana’s oil industry. Extr Ind Soc 7:1238–1245. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.exis.2020.05.013

Orihata M, Watanabe C (2000) The interaction between product concept and institutional inducement: a new driver of product innovation. Technovation 20:11–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0166-4972(99)00107-8

Ottenbacher MC, Harrington RJ (2009) Institutional, cultural and contextual factors: potential drivers of the culinary innovation process. Tour Hosp Res 9:235–249. https://doi.org/10.1057/thr.2009.8

Oyelaran-Oyeyinka B (2006) Systems of innovation and underdevelopment. Sci Technol Soc 11:239–269. https://doi.org/10.1177/097172180601100201

Parrado S (2008) Failed policies but institutional innovation through “layering” and “diffusion” in Spanish central administration. Int J Public Sect Manag 21:230–252. https://doi.org/10.1108/09513550810855672

Parto S (2008) Innovation and economic activity: An institutional analysis of the role of clusters in industrializing economies. J Econ Issues 42:1005–1030. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2008.11507200

Pascucci S, De Magistris T (2011) Institutional innovation and public extension services provision: the marche regional administration reform in central Italy. J Agric Educ Ext 17:267–281. https://doi.org/10.1080/1389224X.2011.559081

Patel S, Burra S (1994) Access to housing finance for the urban poor. Institutional Innovations in India. Cities 11:393–397. https://doi.org/10.1016/0264-2751(94)90072-8

Patterson JJ, Huitema D (2019) Institutional innovation in urban governance: The case of climate change adaptation. J Environ Plan Manag 62:374–398. https://doi.org/10.1080/09640568.2018.1510767

Pearson R, Richardson D (2008) Social capital, institutional innovation and Atlantic trade before 1800. Bus Hist 50:765–780. https://doi.org/10.1080/00076790802420336

Peirce WS (1991) Innovation and diffusion in the “Single Europe”. Institutional structure and industrial prospects for the European Communities. Technol Forecast Soc Change 39:35–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/0040-1625(91)90027-D

Perry KK (2021) Innovation, institutions and development: A critical review and grounded heterodox economic analysis of late-industrialising contexts. Cambridge J Econ 44:391–415. https://doi.org/10.1093/CJE/BEZ049

Pesti P, Effendi N, Cahyandito MF (2019) The influence of institution partnership and innovation management on the smart city reputation. J Entrep Educ 22(3):1–11

Petruzzelli AM, Rotolo D (2015) Institutional diversity, internal search behaviour, and joint-innovations. Manag Decis 53:2088–2106. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-05-2014-0256

Pfister C, Koomen M, Harhoff D, Backes-Gellner U (2021) Regional innovation effects of applied research institutions. Res Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2021.104197

Phakathi S, Sinyolo S, Marire J, Fraser G (2021) Farmer-led institutional innovations in managing smallholder irrigation schemes in KwaZulu-Natal and Eastern Cape Provinces. South Africa Agric Water Manag. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agwat.2021.106780

Phornlaphatrachakorn K (2019) Effects of transformational leadership, organisational learning and technological innovation on strategic management accounting in thailand’s financial institutions. Asian J Bus Account 12:165–188. https://doi.org/10.22452/ajba.vol12no1.6

Piana BD, Vecchi A, Vivacqua E (2015) Innovation, institutions and cultures: exploring the European context. Manag Rev 26:5–24. https://doi.org/10.1688/mrev-2015-01-Della-Piana

Pinho JC (2017) Institutional theory and global entrepreneurship: exploring differences between factor- versus innovation-driven countries. J Int Entrep 15:56–84. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10843-016-0193-9

Pistor K (2009) Global network finance: institutional innovation in the global financial market place. J Comp Econ 37:552–567. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2009.08.002

Polopolus L (1969) On institutional obsolescence and innovation. Am J Agric Econ 51:1624–1628. https://doi.org/10.2307/1238060

Polzin F, von Flotow P, Klerkx L (2016) Addressing barriers to eco-innovation: exploring the finance mobilisation functions of institutional innovation intermediaries. Technol Forecast Soc Change 103:34–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2015.10.001

Pred A (1978) The impact of technological and institutional innovations on life content: some time-geographic observations. Geogr Anal 10:345–372. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4632.1978.tb00664.x

Qing Y, Chen M, Sheng Y, Huang J (2019) Mechanization services, farm productivity and institutional innovation in China. China Agric Econ Rev 11:536–554. https://doi.org/10.1108/CAER-12-2018-0244

Qu Y, Qu T, Wu Y (2017) The role of regional formal institutions and foreign direct investment in innovation in Chinese enterprises. Asia Pacific Bus Rev 23:27–43. https://doi.org/10.1080/13602381.2015.1094293

Quiroga MC, Martin DP (2017) Technology foresight in traditional Bolivian sectors: innovation traps and temporal unfit between ecosystems and institutions. Technol Forecast Soc Change 119:280–293. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.06.023

Radaelli G, Currie G, Frattini F, Lettieri E (2017) The role of managers in enacting two-step institutional work for radical innovation in professional organizations. J Prod Innov Manag 34:450–470. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12385

Raffaelli R, Glynn MA (2015) Institutional innovation: novel, useful, and legitimate. In: Shalley C, Hitt MA, Zhou J (eds) The Oxford handbook of creativity, innovation, and entrepreneurship. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 407–420

Raghubanshi G, Venugopal S, Saini GK (2021) Fostering inclusive social innovation in subsistence marketplaces through community-level alliances: an institutional work perspective. Ind Mark Manag 97:21–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2021.06.009

Rahman MM, Khan MA, Mohammad N, Rahman MO (2009) Cyberspace claiming new dynamism in the jurisprudential philosophy. Int J Law Manag 51:274–290. https://doi.org/10.1108/17542430910988883

Rahman HM, Sherren K, van Proosdij D (2019) Institutional Innovation for Nature-Based Coastal Adaptation: Lessons from Salt Marsh Restoration in Nova Scotia. Canada. Sustainability 11:6735. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11236735

Ransdell J (2019) Institutional innovation by the Asian infrastructure investment bank. Asian J Int Law 9:125–152. https://doi.org/10.1017/S2044251318000176

Rasiah R (1996) Innovation and institutions: moving towards the technological frontier in the electronics industry in Malaysia. J Ind Stud 3:78–102

Rasiah R, Shahrivar RB, Yap X-S (2016) Institutional support, innovation capabilities and exports: evidence from the semiconductor industry in Taiwan. Technol Forecast Soc Change 109:69–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.05.015

Reed M, Wallace M (2015) Elite discourse and institutional innovation: making the hybrid happen in English public services. Res Sociol Organ 43:269–302. https://doi.org/10.1108/S0733-558X20150000043022

Regan PM (1993) Data integrity boards: institutional innovation and congressional oversight. Gov Inf Q 10:443–459. https://doi.org/10.1016/0740-624X(93)90040-7

Riccomini FE, Cirani CBS, Pedro SDC et al (2021) Innovation in educational marketing: a study applied to Brazilian private higher education institutions. J Mark High Educ. https://doi.org/10.1080/08841241.2021.1966157

Richardson J (1979) Institutional innovation: organizing for better international relationships. Ann Am Acad Pol Soc Sci 442:117–124. https://doi.org/10.1177/000271627944200114

Rickards T, De Cock C, Moger S et al (1996) Process: Implementation as a form of institutional innovation. Creat Innov Manag 5:252–259. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8691.1996.tb00151.x

Robin S, Schubert T (2013) Cooperation with public research institutions and success in innovation: evidence from France and Germany. Res Policy 42:149–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2012.06.002

Rodima-Taylor D, Olwig MF, Chhetri N (2012) Adaptation as innovation, innovation as adaptation: an institutional approach to climate change. Appl Geogr 33:107–111. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apgeog.2011.10.011

Rodríguez-Pose A, Zhang M (2020) The cost of weak institutions for innovation in China. Technol Forecast Soc Change. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2020.119937

Rolfstam M (2012) An institutional approach to research on public procurement of innovation. Innov Eur J Soc Sci Res 25:303–321. https://doi.org/10.1080/13511610.2012.717475

Rong Z, Wu X, Boeing P (2017) The effect of institutional ownership on firm innovation: evidence from Chinese listed firms. Res Policy 46:1533–1551. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2017.05.013

Rosário FJP, Santa Rita LP, de Albuquerque PP (2013) Technology, relationship and support institutions on sectoral systems of innovation and production in Brazil’s northwest bio ethanol and sugar agro-industry. J Technol Manag Innov 8:285–303

Rosenbusch N, Gusenbauer M, Hatak I et al (2019) Innovation offshoring, institutional context and innovation performance: a meta-analysis. J Manag Stud 56:203–233. https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12407

Ross SA (1989) Institutional markets, financial marketing, and financial innovation. J Finance 44:541. https://doi.org/10.2307/2328769

Ruan L, Liu H (2021) The impact of institutional innovation on internal control: evidence from Chinese state-owned enterprises. Int J Technol Manag 85:255–273. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTM.2021.115264

Rutherford TD (2001) The state of training: learning, institutional innovation, and local boards for training and adjustment in Ontario, Canada. Environ Plan A Econ Sp 33:1871–1891. https://doi.org/10.1068/a33209

Ruttan VW (1989) Institutional innovation and agricultural development. World Dev 17:1375–1387. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(89)90079-X

Ruttan VW (2006) Social science knowledge and induced institutional innovation: an institutional design perspective. J Institutional Econ 2:249–272. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137406000403

Ruttan VW, Hayami Y (1984) Toward a theory of induced institutional innovation. J Dev Stud 20:203–223. https://doi.org/10.1080/00220388408421914

Saka-Helmhout A, Chappin M, Vermeulen P (2020) Multiple paths to firm innovation in sub-saharan Africa: how informal institutions matter. Organ Stud 41:1551–1575. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840619882971

Sakaki H, Jory SR (2019) Institutional investors’ ownership stability and firms’ innovation. J Bus Res 103:10–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.05.032

Salandra R (2018) Knowledge dissemination in clinical trials: exploring influences of institutional support and type of innovation on selective reporting. Res Policy 47:1215–1228. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2018.04.005

Sandberg M (2007) The evolution of IT innovations in Swedish organizations: a Darwinian critique of “Lamarckian” institutional economics. J Evol Econ 17:1–23. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-006-0029-1

Sanginga PC, Abenakyo A, Kamugisha R et al (2010) Tracking outcomes of social capital and institutional innovations in natural resources management: methodological issues and empirical evidence from participatory Bylaw Reform in Uganda. Soc Nat Resour 23:711–725. https://doi.org/10.1080/08941920802192207

Sartor MA, Beamish PW (2014) Offshoring innovation to emerging markets: organizational control and informal institutional distance. J Int Bus Stud 45:1072–1095. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2014.36

Sawang S, Zhou Y, Yang X (2017) Does institutional context matter in building innovation capability? Int J Technol Learn Innov Dev 9:153–168. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTLID.2017.084933

Schickler E (2001) Disjointed pluralism: institutional innovation and the development of the US Congress. Princeton University Press, Princeton

Schofield N (2000) Institutional innovation, contingency and war: a review. Soc Choice Welfare 17:463–479. https://doi.org/10.1007/s003550050173

Schøtt T, Jensen KW (2016) Firms’ innovation benefiting from networking and institutional support: A global analysis of national and firm effects. Res Policy 45:1233–1246. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.03.006

Schütz F, Schroth F, Muschner A, Schraudner M (2018) Defining functional roles for research institutions in helix innovation networks. J Technol Manag Innov 13:47–53. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-27242018000400047

Scott WR (2006) Institutions and organisations. Sage, Thousand Oaks

Sein-Echaluce ML, Abadía-Valle AR, Bueno-García C, Fidalgo-Blanco Á (2017) Interaction of knowledge spirals to create ontologies for an institutional repository of educational innovation best practices. Int J Hum Cap Inf Technol Prof 8:72–92. https://doi.org/10.4018/IJHCITP.2017040105

Sena V, Marra M, Demirbag M, Lubrano Lavadera G (2021) The Impact of Institutions on Collaborative Innovations and the Role of Equity-Based Entry Modes. Br J Manag. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8551.12511

Sewell WRD, Coppock JT, Pitkethly A (2005) Institutional innovation in water management: the Scottish experience. Routledge, London

Sha K, Song T, Qi X, Luo N (2006) Rethinking China’s urbanization: an institutional innovation perspective. Build Res Inf 34:573–583. https://doi.org/10.1080/09613210600852730

Shackleton M, Raunio T (2003) Codecision since Amsterdam: a laboratory for institutional innovation and change. J Eur Public Policy 10:171–188. https://doi.org/10.1080/1350176032000058982

Shaffer JD (1969) On institutional obsolescence and innovation-background for professional dialogue on public policy. Am J Agric Econ 51:245–267. https://doi.org/10.2307/1237577

Shang Y, Fagan M (2006) Catalysing institutional innovation. Int J Technol Glob 2:340. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJTG.2006.011921

Sharma MK, Sharma RC (2021) Innovation framework for excellence in higher education institutions. Glob J Flex Syst Manag 22:141–155. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40171-021-00265-x

Sharma U, Lawrence S, Lowe A (2010) Institutional contradiction and management control innovation: A field study of total quality management practices in a privatized telecommunication company. Manag Account Res 21:251–264. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.mar.2010.03.005

Shin D-H (2004) Inter-institutional communications and process innovation: inter-institutional system and collaborative work process. J Comput Inf Technol 12:55. https://doi.org/10.2498/cit.2004.01.05

Shu C, Zhou KZ, Xiao Y, Gao S (2016) How green management influences product innovation in China: the role of institutional benefits. J Bus Ethics 133:471–485. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2401-7

Siltaloppi J, Koskela-Huotari K, Vargo SL (2016) Institutional complexity as a driver for innovation in service ecosystems. Serv Sci 8:333–343. https://doi.org/10.1287/serv.2016.0151

Simmie J, Strambach S (2006) The contribution of KIBS to innovation in cities: an evolutionary and institutional perspective. J Knowl Manag 10:26–40. https://doi.org/10.1108/13673270610691152

Simpson J (2005) Cooperation and conflicts: institutional innovation in France’s wine markets, 1870–1911. Bus Hist Rev 79:527–558. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007680500081435

Singh VP, Allen T (2006) Institutional contexts for scientific innovation and economic transformation. Eur Plan Stud 14:665–679. https://doi.org/10.1080/09654310500500205

Smink MM, Hekkert MP, Negro SO (2015) Keeping sustainable innovation on a leash? Exploring incumbents’ institutional strategies. Bus Strateg Environ 24:86–101. https://doi.org/10.1002/bse.1808

Smith N, Thomas E (2015) Socio-institutional environment and innovation in Russia. J East-West Bus 21:182–204. https://doi.org/10.1080/10669868.2015.1021066

Styhre A, Remneland-Wikhamn B (2016) The institutional work of life science innovation leadership: the case of a bio venture hub. Qual Res Organ Manag an Int J 11:253–275. https://doi.org/10.1108/QROM-10-2015-1331

Sun F, Hong J, Ma X, Wang C (2017) Subnational institutions and open innovation: evidence from China. Manag Decis 55:1942–1955. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-11-2016-0781

Suparjo ESS (2017) Professional competence and service innovation in higher education institutions in central Java, Indonesia. Eur Res Stud J XX:622–636. https://doi.org/10.35808/ersj/916

Sus M (2019) Institutional innovation of EU’s foreign and security policy: Big leap for EU’s strategic actorness or much ADO about nothing? Int Polit 56:411–425. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41311-017-0133-x

Suzuki M (2015) Identifying roles of international institutions in clean energy technology innovation and diffusion in the developing countries: matching barriers with roles of the institutions. J Clean Prod 98:229–240. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.08.070

Tang Y, Hu X, Petti C, Thürer M (2020a) Institutional incentives and pressures in Chinese manufacturing firms’ innovation. Manag Decis 58:812–827. https://doi.org/10.1108/MD-08-2018-0933

Tang Y, Hu X, Petti C, Thürer M (2020b) Institution-driven innovation in Guangdong firms: moderating effects of in-house formal R&D and industrial environment turbulence. Sci Public Policy 47:194–206. https://doi.org/10.1093/scipol/scz058

Tao Q, Jinchuan S (2008) Taizhou Model: Institutional Innovation and the Development of Private Economy. China World Econ 16:106–119. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1749-124X.2008.00117.x

Thani FN, Mazari E, Asadi S, Mashayekhikhi M (2021) The impact of self-development on the tendency toward organizational innovation in higher education institutions with the mediating role of human resource agility. J Appl Res High Educ Ahead-of-P. https://doi.org/10.1108/JARHE-05-2020-0151

Ting L, Xin CQ, Qian YQ (2020) The influence of collaborative innovation among technology, institution and finance on China’s economic growth. WSEAS Trans Bus Econ 17:796–805. https://doi.org/10.37394/23207.2020.17.78

Tingey M, Webb J (2020) Governance institutions and prospects for local energy innovation: laggards and leaders among UK local authorities. Energy Policy. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2019.111211

Tolbert CJ, Mossberger K, McNeal R (2008) Institutions, policy innovation, and e-government in the American States. Public Adm Rev 68:549–563. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6210.2008.00890.x

Tomizawa A, Zhao L, Bassellier G, Ahlstrom D (2020) Economic growth, innovation, institutions, and the Great Enrichment. Asia Pacific J Manag 37:7–31. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-019-09648-2

Torres de Oliveira R, Verreynne M-L, Figueira S et al (2020) How do institutional innovation systems affect open innovation? J Small Bus Manag. https://doi.org/10.1080/00472778.2020.1775466

Tumbas S, Berente N, vom Brocke J (2018) Digital innovation and institutional entrepreneurship: chief digital officer perspectives of their emerging role. J Inf Technol 33:188–202. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41265-018-0055-0

Turker D, Vural CA (2017) Embedding social innovation process into the institutional context: Voids or supports. Technol Forecast Soc Change 119:98–113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.03.019

Tyson LD (1979) Incentives, income sharing, and institutional innovation in the yugoslav self-managed firm. J Comp Econ 3:285–301. https://doi.org/10.1016/0147-5967(79)90030-1

Unger B, Zagler M (2003) Institutional and organizational determinants of product innovations. Innovation 16:293–310. https://doi.org/10.1080/1351161032000126035

Van Bockhaven WMG, Matthyssens P, Vandenbempt K (2015) Drivers of institutional innovation in networks: Unleashing the innovation potential of domesticated markets. J Bus Ind Mark 30:414–435. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBIM-10-2013-0220

van der Heijden J, Kuhlmann J (2017) Studying incremental institutional change: a systematic and critical meta-review of the literature from 2005 to 2015. Policy Stud J 45:535–554. https://doi.org/10.1111/psj.12191

van der Krabben E, Lenferink S (2018) The introduction of urban land readjustment legislation as an institutional innovation in Dutch land policy. Habitat Int 75:114–121. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.habitatint.2018.03.004

van Dijk S, Berends H, Jelinek M et al (2011) Micro-institutional affordances and strategies of radical innovation. Organ Stud 32:1485–1513. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840611421253

van Waarden F (2001) Institutions and innovation: the legal environment of innovating firms. Organ Stud 22:765–795. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840601225002

Van Wijk J, Van der Duim R, Lamers M, Sumba D (2015) The emergence of institutional innovations in tourism: the evolution of the African Wildlife Foundation’s tourism conservation enterprises. J Sustain Tour 23:104–125. https://doi.org/10.1080/09669582.2014.927878

van Wijk J, Zietsma C, Dorado S et al (2019) Social innovation: integrating micro, meso, and macro level insights from institutional theory. Bus Soc 58:887–918. https://doi.org/10.1177/0007650318789104

Vasudeva G (2009) How national institutions influence technology policies and firms’ knowledge-building strategies: A study of fuel cell innovation across industrialized countries. Res Policy 38:1248–1259. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2009.05.006

Vecchi A, Della Piana B, Vivacqua E (2015) An Institutional-based view of innovation - an explorative comparison of business groups in China and India. Int J Innov Manag. https://doi.org/10.1142/S1363919615500516

Veiga PM, Teixeira SJ, Figueiredo R, Fernandes CI (2020) Entrepreneurship, innovation and competitiveness: a public institution love triangle. Socioecon Plann Sci. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2020.100863

Velho L (2004) Building social science research capacity in Bolivia: an institutional innovation. Int Soc Sci J 56:257–270. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0020-8701.2004.00488.x

Ventura R, Quero MJ, Díaz-Méndez M (2020) The role of institutions in achieving radical innovation. Mark Intell Plan 38:310–324. https://doi.org/10.1108/MIP-01-2019-0050

Venugopal S, Viswanathan M (2019) Implementation of social innovations in subsistence marketplaces: a facilitated institutional change process model. J Prod Innov Manag 36:800–823. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12508

Vermeulen P, Büch R, Greenwood R et al (2007a) The impact of governmental policies in institutional fields: the case of innovation in the Dutch concrete industry. Organ Stud 28:515–540. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840606067927

Vermeulen PAM, Van Den Bosch FAJ, Volberda HW (2007b) Complex incremental product innovation in established service firms: a micro institutional perspective. Organ Stud 28:1523–1546. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840607068082

Vickers I, Lyon F, Sepulveda L, McMullin C (2017) Public service innovation and multiple institutional logics: The case of hybrid social enterprise providers of health and wellbeing. Res Policy 46:1755–1768. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2017.08.003

Villavicencio GJD, Didonet SR, Dodd A (2015) Innovation: an institutional approach. Espacios 36:13

Vines R, Jones M, McCarthy G (2015) Collaborating across institutional and jurisdictional boundaries: Enabling the emergence of a national innovation system through public knowledge management. Knowl Manag Res Pract 13:187–197. https://doi.org/10.1057/kmrp.2013.41

Waldorff SB (2013) Accounting for organizational innovations: mobilizing institutional logics in translation. Scand J Manag 29:219–234. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scaman.2013.03.010

Wallman JP (2009) An examination of Peter Drucker’s work from an institutional perspective: how institutional innovation creates value leadership. J Acad Mark Sci 37:61–72. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-008-0104-2

Wang C, Alvarez-Gaitan JP, Moore S, Stuetz R (2019a) Social and institutional factors affecting sustainability innovation in universities: a computer re-use perspective. J Clean Prod 223:176–188. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.03.093

Wang C, Yi J, Kafouros M, Yan Y (2015) Under what institutional conditions do business groups enhance innovation performance? J Bus Res 68:694–702. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2014.08.002

Wang H, Zhao Y, Dang B et al (2019b) Network centrality and innovation performance: the role of formal and informal institutions in emerging economies. J Bus Ind Mark 34:1388–1400. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBIM-09-2017-0228

Wang J, Deng J (2021) Research on the effect of executive incentive institutional innovation on the cost of equity—evidence from chinese listed companies. Front Psychol. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2021.686955

Wang L, Huang Z (2020) Research on the synergetic innovation between pharmaceutical enterprises and scientific research institutions based on the quantum game. IEEE Access 8:63718–63724. https://doi.org/10.1109/ACCESS.2020.2976544

Wang P, Swanson EB (2007) Launching professional services automation: institutional entrepreneurship for information technology innovations. Inf Organ 17:59–88. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoandorg.2007.02.001

Watkins A, Papaioannou T, Mugwagwa J, Kale D (2015) National innovation systems and the intermediary role of industry associations in building institutional capacities for innovation in developing countries: a critical review of the literature. Res Policy 44:1407–1418. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2015.05.004

Watt DC (2002) The ‘War’ against terror and the need for institutional innovation. Polit Q 73:288–298. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-923X.00469

Weber F, Lehmann J, Graf-Vlachy L, König A (2019) Institution-infused sensemaking of discontinuous innovations: the case of the sharing economy. J Prod Innov Manag 36:632–660. https://doi.org/10.1111/jpim.12499

Webster A, Gardner J (2019) Aligning technology and institutional readiness: the adoption of innovation. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 31:1229–1241. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537325.2019.1601694

Whitley R (2014) How do institutional changes affect scientific innovations? the effects of shifts in authority relationships, protected space, and flexibility. Res Sociol Organ 42:367–406. https://doi.org/10.1108/S0733-558X20140000042012

Whitley R (2000) The institutional structuring of innovation strategies: business systems, firm types and patterns of technical change in different market economies. Organ Stud 21:855–886. https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840600215002

Widyani AAD (2019) Innovation and performance antecedents of village credit institutions in Bali province. J Manag Inf Decis Sci 22:101–106

Wiklund H, Klefsjö B, Wiklund PS, Edvardsson B (2003) Innovation and TQM in Swedish higher education institutions possibilities and pitfalls. TQM Mag 15:99–107. https://doi.org/10.1108/09544780310461116

Williams ME (2002) Market reforms, technocrats, and institutional innovation. World Dev 30:395–412. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00116-4

Windrum P, Schartinger D, Waring J (2018) Co-creation of social innovations and new professional institutions: diffusion of therapeutic patient education (TPE) for diabetes in Austria. Ind Innov 25:570–593. https://doi.org/10.1080/13662716.2017.1295363

Wiskerke JSC, Roep D (2007) Constructing a sustainable pork supply chain: a case of techno-institutional innovation. J Environ Policy Plan 9:53–74. https://doi.org/10.1080/15239080701254982

Woodhill J (2010) Capacities for institutional innovation: a complexity perspective. IDS Bull 41:47–59. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1759-5436.2010.00136.x

Wu J (2013) Diverse institutional environments and product innovation of emerging market firms. Manag Int Rev 53:39–59. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11575-012-0162-z

Wu J, Ma Z, Liu Z, Lei CK (2019) A contingent view of institutional environment, firm capability, and innovation performance of emerging multinational enterprises. Ind Mark Manag 82:148–157. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.indmarman.2019.01.018

Wu J, Park SH (2019) The role of international institutional complexity on emerging market multinational companies’ innovation. Glob Strateg J 9:333–353. https://doi.org/10.1002/gsj.1166

Wu J, Wang C, Hong J et al (2016) Internationalization and innovation performance of emerging market enterprises: The role of host-country institutional development. J World Bus 51:251–263. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jwb.2015.09.002

Wu J, Wu Z, Zhuo S (2015) The effects of institutional quality and diversity of foreign markets on exporting firms’ innovation. Int Bus Rev 24:1095–1106. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ibusrev.2015.05.001

Wu Y, Yang Y, Xu W, Chen Q (2020) The influence of innovation resources in higher education institutions on the development of Sci-tech parks’ enterprises in the urban innovative districts at the stage of urbanization transformation. Land 9:1–36. https://doi.org/10.3390/land9100396

Xie A (2006) Institutional innovation and systematic construction of teacher education in the transformational period. Front Educ China 1:201–211. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11516-006-0003-6

Xie J, Yang Y (2021) IoT-based model for intelligent innovation practice system in higher education institutions. J Intell Fuzzy Syst 40:2861–2870. https://doi.org/10.3233/JIFS-189326

Xie X, Wu Y, Xie P et al (2019) Organizational innovation culture and firms’ new product performance in two emerging markets: The moderating effects of institutional environments and organizational cohesion. J Manag Organ. https://doi.org/10.1017/jmo.2019.8

Xu H, Wang C, Dong K et al (2020) A study of methods to identify industry-university-research institution cooperation partners based on innovation Chain theory. J Data Inf Sci 3:38–61. https://doi.org/10.2478/jdis-2018-0008

Yang D, Jiao H, Buckland R (2017) The determinants of financial fraud in Chinese firms: does corporate governance as an institutional innovation matter? Technol Forecast Soc Change 125:309–320. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2017.06.035

Yang D, Wang AX, Zhou KZ, Jiang W (2019) Environmental strategy, institutional force, and innovation capability: a managerial cognition perspective. J Bus Ethics 159:1147–1161. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-018-3830-5

Yang G (2018) The cost of institutional innovation in the absence of an external governance mechanism—a case study on the ‘Alibaba Partnership.’ China J Account Stud 6:498–526. https://doi.org/10.1080/21697213.2019.1612192

Yang J, Al-Sayed R (2021) Barriers to radical innovation in research institutions in China. Int J Innov Sci Ahead-of-P. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJIS-04-2021-0075

Yang K (2016) Creating Public Value and Institutional Innovations across Boundaries: An Integrative Process of Participation, Legitimation, and Implementation. Public Adm Rev 76:873–885. https://doi.org/10.1111/puar.12561

Yano G, Shiraishi M (2020) Finance, institutions, and innovation activities in China. Econ Syst. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecosys.2020.100835

Yao Q, Liu J, Sheng S, Fang H (2019) Does eco-innovation lift firm value? The contingent role of institutions in emerging markets. J Bus Ind Mark 34:1763–1778. https://doi.org/10.1108/JBIM-06-2018-0201

Yao Q, Zeng S, Sheng S, Gong S (2021) Green innovation and brand equity: moderating effects of industrial institutions. Asia Pacific J Manag 38:573–602. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-019-09664-2

Yau Y, Lau W (2018) Big data approach as an institutional innovation to Tackle Hong Kong’s illegal subdivided unit problem. Sustainability 10:2709. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082709

Yeung SM-C (2015) Innovation in the application of gri to visualize strategic goals for sustainable development – The case of tertiary institution, Hong Kong. Corp Ownersh Control 12:572–585

Yi J, Hong J, Hsu WC, Wang C (2017) The role of state ownership and institutions in the innovation performance of emerging market enterprises: evidence from China. Technovation 62–63:4–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2017.04.002

Yi Y, Liu Y, He H, Li Y (2012) Environment, governance, controls, and radical innovation during institutional transitions. Asia Pacific J Manag 29:689–708. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-010-9231-7

Yingbo L, Jiankun H, Li Z (2010) The transfer of innovation capability from universities to enterprises in China: An institutional framework. Int J Manag Enterp Dev 9:385–404. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJMED.2010.037565

Yoshikawa T, Tsui-Auch LS, McGuire J (2007) Corporate governance reform as institutional innovation: The case of Japan. Organ Sci 18:973–988. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.1070.0290

Yu X, Paudel KP, Li D et al (2020) Sustainable collaborative innovation between research institutions and seed enterprises in China. Sustain. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12020624

Yu Z (2020) Beyond the state/market dichotomy: institutional innovations in China’s electricity industry reform. J Environ Manage. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2020.110306

Zapata-Cantu L, González F (2021) Challenges for innovation and sustainable development in Latin America: the significance of institutions and human capital. Sustainability 13:4077. https://doi.org/10.3390/su13074077

Zhang K, Putzel L (2016) Institutional innovation and forest landscape restoration in China: Multi-scale cross-sector networking, household fiscal modernization and tenure reform. World Dev Perspect 3:18–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wdp.2016.11.002

Zhang Y, Tan W (2019) The leading small group: an institutional innovation for PPP projects in China. Built Environ Proj Asset Manag 9:291–301. https://doi.org/10.1108/BEPAM-12-2017-0132

Zhu Y, Wittmann X, Peng MW (2012) Institution-based barriers to innovation in SMEs in China. Asia Pacific J Manag 29:1131–1142. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10490-011-9263-7

Zweifel P (1995) Diffusion of hospital innovations in different institutional settings. Int J Econ Bus 2:465–483. https://doi.org/10.1080/758538017

Download references

The authors declare that no funds, grants, or other support were received during the preparation of this manuscript.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Innovation and Technology Management, Arabian Gulf University, Manama, Bahrain

Hameeda A. AlMalki & Christopher M. Durugbo

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher M. Durugbo .

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest.

The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

AlMalki, H.A., Durugbo, C.M. Systematic review of institutional innovation literature: towards a multi-level management model. Manag Rev Q 73 , 731–785 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11301-022-00259-8

Download citation

Received : 29 April 2021

Accepted : 05 January 2022

Published : 02 February 2022

Issue Date : June 2023

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s11301-022-00259-8

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Institutional innovation
  • Institutional change
  • Knowledge externalities
  • Economic conditions
  • Institutional theory

JEL Classification

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

Tax morale and institutional theory: a systematic review

International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy

ISSN : 0144-333X

Article publication date: 6 August 2018

Issue publication date: 17 August 2018

The purpose of this paper is to conduct a systematic review of the factors that shape tax morale. A large range of random explanatory variables identified in the literature as determinants of tax morale are synthesised and structured by drawing inspiration from the institutional theory.

Design/methodology/approach

To do this, a systematic search has been conducted using a library catalogue which provides access to more than 400 databases.

The finding is that the institutional theory provides a suitable theoretical basis to explore tax morale. Indeed, all the factors until now identified as determinants of tax morale (except the control variables/socio-demographic characteristics) can be categorised either as belonging to formal institutions or to informal institutions. The most salient factor is trust, with both vertical and horizontal trust positively related to tax morale.

Research limitations/implications

The outcome is a call for a more nuanced understanding of not only the effect of formal and informal institutions on tax morale but also how formal and informal institutions interact and alter each other and, consequently, affect tax morale.

Practical implications

The paper seeks to encourage governments to start recognising that as low tax morale arises when a gap exists between formal and informal institutions, they need to design policy measures aimed to reduce this gap, rather than persisting with deterrence measures.

Originality/value

This is the first systematic review of the factors that influence tax morale using an institutionalist lens.

  • Informal institutions
  • Tax compliance
  • Formal institutions
  • Horizontal trust
  • Vertical trust

Horodnic, I.A. (2018), "Tax morale and institutional theory: a systematic review", International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy , Vol. 38 No. 9/10, pp. 868-886. https://doi.org/10.1108/IJSSP-03-2018-0039

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2018, Ioana Alexandra Horodnic

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial & non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode

1. Introduction

Tax compliance has been extensively researched and yet, the question of why people pay taxes remains only partially answered. Tax non-compliance continues to represent a core issue for many governments around the world.

For many decades, the neoclassical approach developed by Allingham and Sandmo (1972) represented the benchmark economic model of tax non-compliance. The model assumes that tax payers are rational actors who seek to maximise the utility of their taxable income by weighting the benefits and the cost of compliance with the utility of tax non-compliance. As such, they will be non-compliant when the expected penalty and probability of being caught are rather small compared to the utility gained by non-compliance. As a result, the governments sought to ensure that the utility of non-compliance is outweighed by the cost of non-compliance and increased the penalties and the perceived probability of detection of the non-compliant taxpayers ( Williams, 2014 ; Williams and Horodnic, 2015a, 2017a ). However, reducing tax non-compliance is not just a matter of applying higher penalties and/or increasing the probability of detection. The first to recognise that the model does not capture all the rationales of tax non-compliance were the authors themselves as they state in their paper the following: “This is a very simple theory, and it may perhaps be criticized for giving too little attention to nonpecuniary factors in the taxpayer’s decision on whether or not to evade taxes” ( Allingham and Sandmo, 1972 ). Indeed, despite its simplicity and clear-cut policy implications, the model fails to explain why the observed level of tax compliance is higher than the theoretical predicted level ( Leonardo, 2011 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a ). That stimulated the search for alternative models which take into account the non-pecuniary aspects of the tax compliance decision. As such, after being neglected for decades, starting in the 1990s, tax morale turned into a key issue in the recent empirical research on tax compliance ( Torgler, 2011 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a ).

The aim of this paper is to conduct a systematic review of the factors that influence tax morale. To do so, a large range of random explanatory variables identified in the literature as determinants of tax morale are synthesised and structured by drawing inspiration from institutional theory ( Baumol and Blinder, 2008 ; Helmke and Levitsky, 2004 ; North, 1990 ). As such, tax morale is viewed in this paper primarily as a result of the interaction between the formal and the informal institutions. An asymmetry in a society between the laws and regulations of its formal institutions and the socially shared unwritten norms of its informal institutions will result in low tax morale. In Section 1 , therefore, the importance of tax morale in explaining various forms of tax non-compliance will be briefly reviewed, followed by the methodology and a structured analysis of the effect of formal and informal institutions on tax morale, alongside the socio-demographic characteristics related to the variations in tax morale. The paper concludes by discussing the tentative policy implications and the identified gaps in the literature.

2. Tax morale and tax compliance

The concept of tax morale was introduced for the first time during the 1960s by “Cologne school of tax psychology” ( Schmӧlders, 1970 ; Strümpel, 1969 ) but received little attention from tax researchers for several decades ( Alm and Torgler, 2004 ). Starting in the 1990s, tax morale increasingly attracted attention and has become a central issue in empirical research on tax compliance ( Torgler, 2011 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a ). Tax morale is defined most often as the intrinsic motivation to pay taxes ( Torgler, 2002b, 2005c, 2012 ; Torgler and Schneider, 2007a ). Luttmer and Singhal (2014) define tax morale as the totality of non-pecuniary motivations and factors for tax compliance which fall outside the expected utility maximisation. As mentioned above, in this paper, using an institutionalist lens, the intrinsic motivation to pay taxes, tax morale, is viewed primarily to result from the interaction between formal and informal institutions. However, it is important to acknowledge that personal traits are also important in shaping the individual’s tax morale and thus, tax compliance behaviour. Previous studies show that there are individuals, referred to as “honest taxpayers”, which do not try to evade ( Torgler, 2001, 2003c ) because they are simply “predisposed not to evade” ( Long and Swingen, 1991 ). The opposite extreme is represented by the “tax evaders” who, in general, have a low tax morale and act as rational actors comparing the benefits of evading taxes to the benefits of complying ( Torgler, 2003c ). Furthermore, there are individuals who may enjoy evading taxes and perceive this as a game, playing with the state ( Kirchler et al. , 2007 ).

A literature review investigating if tax morale represents a significant factor that affects tax compliance or rather a marginal one concluded that tax morale plays a sizeable role in explaining tax compliance decisions ( Luttmer and Singhal, 2014 ). Further support in this direction is provided by the study conducted on the particular case of the Protestant church in Bavaria, where tax enforcement is limited or non-existent and where the results show that about 20 per cent of the individuals paid taxes despite the lack of enforcement ( Dwenger et al. , 2016 ). Indeed, although a high level of tax morality (i.e. an attitude) does not automatically result in a high level of tax compliance (i.e. a behaviour), analysing the results of previous empirical studies, it becomes quickly apparent that tax morale has a strong effect on various forms of tax non-compliant behaviours. Lower levels of tax morale are associated with higher levels of tax evasion/lower levels of tax compliance ( Brink and Porcano, 2016 ; Dell’Anno, 2009 ; Kirchgässner, 2010 ; Lima and Zaklan, 2008 ; Lisi, 2015 ; Stark and Kirchler, 2017 ; Sumartaya and Hafidiah, 2014 ; Torgler, 2004a ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler et al. , 2008 ), higher levels of shadow economy ( Halla, 2012 ; Torgler and Schneider, 2006, 2007a, b, 2009 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a, b ), higher participation in undeclared work ( Williams and Horodnic, 2015c, 2016a ; Windebank and Horodnic, 2017 ) or higher participation in underreporting wages ( Williams and Horodnic, 2015a ,   b,   c,   d,  e, 2016b, 2017a ). Similarly, a large asymmetry between formal and informal institutions was identified as being positively correlated with the informal payments made by patients for healthcare services ( Horodnic and Williams, 2018 ; Williams and Horodnic, 2017, 2018 ).

In order to provide a better understanding of how tax morale is shaped and, therefore, to identify which policies could improve tax morale, the next sections provide a systematic review of the factors that influence tax morale. These factors are grouped into three main categories: formal institutions which include factors related to governance and countries’ structural conditions; informal institutions which include the social influences; and socio-demographic characteristics and personal values.

3. Data and methodology

3.1 data sources.

For identifying the relevant papers related to tax morale, a systematic search has been conducted using Sheffield University’s Library Catalogue which provides access to more than 400 databases, including for example, Ebsco, Econlit, Emerald Insight, Jstor, Proquest, Sage, Science Direct, Scopus and even Google Scholar. That provided access to journal papers, working papers, conference papers, books, thesis dissertations and official reports. The results were displayed by relevance, and we screened the first 300 results generated by using specific keywords. In addition, the references of the selected papers were checked as well as the personal pages of the most relevant authors in the field, in order to avoid the exclusion of important work which might have not appeared in the first search.

3.2 Inclusion criteria

The inclusion criteria were based on the use of the keywords “tax morale” or “tax morality”. No limitation regarding the type or the year of publication was applied. Only the papers written in English have been kept. From the initial 600 results (300 for each keyword), after screening the titles and abstracts less than 200 papers were retained. A detailed review of these papers found 82 papers that analyse the factors affecting tax morale. Only original research papers which have used empirical or theoretical models referring to tax morale as a dependent variable have been kept and displayed in the resultant tables (i.e. those referring to tax compliance as dependent variable are not included). Literature review type papers, if relevant, were used for the introduction or for the concluding part of the paper.

Research articles, conference papers, books, thesis dissertations and official reports were identified and included. When a working paper was subsequently published in a scientific journal, the published version was kept in the analysis.

The array of methods used in the selected papers was heterogeneous, with a predominance of surveys and laboratory experiments. A variety of secondary and primary sources of data has been used, including both cross-country data or individual country data. These include the World Values Survey, the European Values Surveys, the European Social Survey, the Eurobarometer survey on undeclared work, the International Social Survey Programme, the Taxpayer Opinion Survey, the Latinbarometro, the Afrobarometer, the AsiaBarometer, the Australian Graduates’ Hopes, Visions and Actions Survey, the Bank of Italy Survey of Household Wealth and Income, the Palestinian Public Opinion Survey, the Pakistan’s Baseline Taxpayers’ Perception Survey, the Spain’s Survey of Fiscal Policy, the Spain’s Survey into Tax Morale of the Citizenry or primary data collection via a self-designed survey. Tables I–III present the synthetised results collected from the 82 papers included in the systematic review. Due to the space limit, for each identified factor, only the predominant finding is displayed. In the situation that for the same factor an approximately similar number of papers found divergent results, those are kept and discussed (see e.g. the findings on deterrence measures in Table I ).

4.1 Formal institutions and tax morale

trust in the government ( Andriani, 2016 ; Chan et al. , 2018 ; Daude et al. , 2012 ; Ibrahim et al. , 2015 ; Kondelaji et al. , 2016 ; Leonardo, 2011 ; Li, 2010 ; Ristovska et al. , 2013 ; Torgler, 2003b,  d , 2004a, b, 2012 ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler and Schneider, 2004 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a, b ; Trüdinger and Hildebrandt, 2013 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 );

trust in the parliament ( Alm and Torgler, 2006 ; Chan et al. , 2018 ; Frey and Torgler, 2007 ; Martinez-Vazquez and Torgler, 2009 ; Torgler, 2004c, 2005a ; Torgler and Murphy, 2004 ; Torgler and Schneider, 2004 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a );

trust in court and the legal system/rule of law ( Alm and Torgler, 2006 ; Andriani, 2016 ; Feld and Torgler, 2007 ; Filippin et al. , 2013 ; Frey and Torgler, 2007 ; Torgler, 2003a, b, c, 2004a, b,  c , 2005a, b, 2012 ; Torgler and Murphy, 2004 ; Torgler and Schneider, 2004 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a, 2008, 2010 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 );

trust in the tax authority and tax officials ( Jahnke, 2015 ; Torgler, 2003b, c, 2004c ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler et al. , 2008 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 ),

trust in public officials (Torgler and Schaffner, 2007; Torgler et al. , 2008 );

trust in politicians ( Lago-Peñas and Lago-Peñas, 2010 );

trust in the president ( Torgler, 2005b );

trust in political parties ( Chan et al. , 2018 );

trust in police ( Leonardo and Martinez-Vazquez, 2016 ); and

trust in the European Union ( Torgler, 2012 ).

Similarly, a large body of studies concluded that tax morale depends on perceived fairness and effectiveness of the government. As such, the more effective the government spending is perceived ( Alasfour et al. , 2016 ; Barone and Mocetti, 2011 ; Molero and Pujol, 2012 ; Sipos, 2015 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 ) and the higher is the level of the perceived benefits ( Alm and Gomez, 2008 ), the higher the level of tax morale. In addition, the transparency of public spending is associated with higher tax morale ( Sipos, 2015 ). Furthermore, tax morale is improved if the government and the tax system are perceived by the citizens as being fair ( Alasfour et al. , 2016 ; Alm and Gomez, 2008 ; Çevik, 2016 ; Cummings et al. , 2005, 2009 ; Cyan et al. , 2016 ; Frey, 2003 ; Niesiobędzka, 2014 ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler et al. , 2008 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 ).

While the neoclassical approach developed by Allingham and Sandmo (1972) represented the benchmark economic model of tax non-compliance and, therefore, an overwhelming number of studies investigated the effect of the deterrence measures on tax compliance, only a few studies sought to investigate this issue with respect to tax morale and the results are not conclusive. While some studies identified a positive relationship between tax morale and the perceived level of detection or the perceived sanctions ( Torgler and Werner, 2005 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a ; Williams and Horodnic, 2016c ), other studies found no relationship ( Torgler, 2003a, 2005a, c ; Torgler et al. , 2010 ). However, it is important to notice that increased levels of deterrence might disrupt the trust between government and citizens ( Pommerehne and Frey, 1992 ; Torgler, 2001 ).

Finally, a significant body of papers investigate the influence of the country structural conditions on tax morale. A higher level of GDP, higher level of government expenditure and higher level of immigration are positively associated with tax morale. In stark contrast, higher levels of inflation, income inequality and tax rates are negatively associated with citizens’ tax morale. Similarly, widespread corruption is associated with lower tax morale (list of studies in Table I ). This suggests that, in countries where corruption is systemic, citizens have little trust in public authorities and their tax morale decreases because the obligation of paying taxes does not represent an accepted social norm as citizens feel cheated ( Chan et al. , 2018 ; Saitta, 2017 ; Torgler, 2001 ; Torgler et al. , 2007b ). Therefore, evading taxes is used by citizens as a self-defence mechanism.

Tax morale increases where there is a closer relationship between the government and citizens, expressed as legal rights/democracy or local autonomy (list of studies in Table I ). Indeed, studies conducted in different cantons in Switzerland conclude that direct democratic rights (e.g. constitutional initiative, legislative initiative, legislative referendum, financial referendum) have positive effects on both tax morale and the size of the shadow economy ( Torgler, 2005a, c ; Torgler and Schneider, 2004 ; Torgler et al. , 2007b, 2010 ). Similarly, the more extensive is the competence of the local audit courts, which allows a higher transparency of the budget as well as spending the taxes according to the citizens’ preferences, the higher is the tax morale ( Torgler, 2005a ; Torgler et al. , 2007b, 2010 ).

In sum, analysing how formal institutions shape tax morale, it can be concluded that citizens have a higher tax morale with higher levels of modernisation (i.e. higher GDP, more effective social protection measures, lower level of inequalities and corruption), higher trust in public institutions and the fairness and effectiveness of public spending, as well as with higher participation in deciding on how public money is spent.

4.2 Informal institutions and tax morale

In behavioural sciences, individuals are not investigated as isolated entities but rather in relation to their social groups and cultures ( Cullis and Lewis, 1997 ; Steinmo, 2017 ). As such, the individual attitude and behaviour is shaped by the informal institutions which refer to the socially shared unwritten norms, values and beliefs. The violation of social norms results in internal sanctions (i.e. guilt, shame) or external sanctions such as social stigma ( Torgler, 2001 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a ). What is therefore the influence of informal institutions on tax morale?

Starting with culture, which represents broad social norms which are persistent in time ( Luttmer and Singhal, 2014 ), a large body of literature identifies a relationship between the informal institutions and tax morale. Analysing individuals living in the same environment but from different cultures, Kountouris and Remoundou (2013) investigate the level of tax morale of first-generation immigrants in Europe and concludes that the tax morale in the country of origin affects the tax morale of the individuals in the hosting country. Similarly, comparing the tax morale in a similar environment in terms of deterrent measures yet with different cultural features, a higher tax morale was identified in East than in West Germany, which shows that tax morale is driven rather by other factors than deterrents such as informal institutions ( Feld and Torgler, 2007 ; Feld et al. , 2008 ; Torgler, 2002/2003 ). Cross-cultural studies show that there is a significant difference in the level of tax morale between countries and that the level of patriotism directly affects tax morale (list of studies in Table II ). For example, tax morale is lower in Eastern Europe as compared with Western Europe, and this might be explained by the institutional crisis experienced by ex-communist economies ( Frey and Torgler, 2007 ). Indeed, analysing Hofstede’s dimensions of culture, the finding is that the level of tax morale is lower in those cultures where the distance to power is higher ( Brink and Porcano, 2016 ). Turning to religion, no difference in tax morale between different religions has been identified ( Alasfour et al. , 2016 ; Kanniainen and Pääkkönen, 2010 ; Torgler, 2003d ). However, religiosity, measured mostly as the frequency of attendance at church, is positively associated with tax morale (list of studies in Table II ). Similarly, a stronger sense of community in general terms, not only from a religious point of view, positively affects the tax morale. The stronger the feeling of belonging to the community ( Çevik, 2016 ), social responsibility ( Braithwaite and Ahmed, 2005 ; Cyan et al. , 2016 ) and civic participation, measured as active participation in the community, participation in voting or civic duty ( Andriani, 2016 ; Barone and Mocetti, 2011 ; D’Attoma, 2015 ; Filippin et al. , 2013 ; Lubian and Zarri, 2011 ; Molero and Pujol, 2012 ; Russo, 2013 ; Trüdinger and Hildebrandt, 2013 ), the higher the tax morale. Meanwhile, the social disapproval of tax cheaters increases tax morale ( Çevik, 2016 ; Dell’Anno, 2009 ; Vythelingum et al. , 2017 ). In contrast, and related with both horizontal and vertical trust, the intensity of discussing about tax authorities and/or political matters with colleagues, family and friends ( Torgler, 2012 ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler et al. , 2008 ) or political participation ( Sá et al. , 2015 ), has a negative effect on tax morale. This might suggest that the individuals share rather negative experiences related to the public authorities that, in turn, reduce vertical trust and therefore the tax morale of the entire group. Similarly, when discussing with friends and family, if some particular honest individuals become aware that other peers cheat in respect to their tax due, their own tax morale is reduced due to a reduced horizontal trust. Indeed, horizontal trust has a strong impact on the individuals’ tax morale. When the members of a community have a high trust in other taxpayers, their tax morale is increased ( Çevik, 2016 ; Kondelaji et al. , 2016 ; Martins and Gomes, 2014 ; Torgler, 2004a, 2005b ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ; Torgler et al. , 2008 ; Trüdinger and Hildebrandt, 2013 ). In opposition, where the perceived level of tax evasion is high and the other taxpayers are perceived as free riders, citizens’ tax morale is lower ( Alm and Gomez, 2008 ; Çevik, 2016 ; Frey and Torgler, 2007 ; Molero and Pujol, 2012 ; Torgler and Schaffner, 2007 ).

In sum, by analysing the effect of informal institutions it can be concluded that cultures, sub-cultures (within countries), communities and social groups affect tax morale. Individual tax morale is shaped by the behaviour of other members of the community. When tax compliance is considered a social norm and therefore being a cheater leads to exclusion and social disapproval, tax morale increases. On the contrary, where there is a low horizontal trust in a society and individuals perceive that a large share of the population evades taxes, the level of tax morale of honest tax payers is lowered.

4.3 Socio-demographic characteristics and personal values

Table III displays the most prevalent results regarding individuals’ characteristics and the level of tax morale. Unlike the results presented in Tables I and II , where the link between the investigated variables and tax morale represented main research questions of the analysed studies, the socio-demographic characteristics were used in general as control variables and included in the majority of empirical studies. As such, considering the large number of studies and the different sample size and geographical areas, the results were not similar. Table III displays the most prevalent result for each socio-demographic characteristic.

Tax morale is positively related to socio-demographic factors such as age, education, income and life satisfaction, and tends to be lower among upper social class. Tax morale tends to be higher among women and married people. Regarding the employment status, tax morale tends to be higher among pensioners and lower among self-employees, part-time employees, students, housewives/housekeepers, unemployed and those engaged in undeclared work (list of studies in Table III ).

Turning to the individual’s norms and values the findings in previous studies show that a higher moral integrity and a more pronounced feeling of guilt in evading taxes are positively related to tax morale ( Bilgin, 2014 ; Dell’Anno, 2009 ; McKerchar et al. , 2013 ; Torgler, 2006 ). Similarly, with the results regarding the level of democracy as a structural condition, the individuals’ support for democracy and democratic values are positively related to tax morale ( Daude et al. , 2012 ; Leonardo, 2011 ; Leonardo and Martinez-Vazquez, 2016 ; Torgler, 2003b, 2004b ; Torgler and Schneider, 2004 ). In contrast, a higher aversion to ethnic diversity is associated to lower tax morale ( Belmonte et al. , 2018 ).

In sum, this section provided support for identifying the individual socio-demographic characteristics of those more likely to have a lower tax morale (i.e. younger people, male, housekeepers and unemployed or undeclared workers, those with low income, etc.) which might represent the target groups for policy measures related to awareness campaigns, tax education, etc.

5. Conclusions and policy implications

This paper has provided a systematic review of the factors related to tax morale. Drawing inspiration from the institutional theory ( Baumol and Blinder, 2008 ; Helmke and Levitsky, 2004 ; North, 1990 ), tax morale has been viewed in this paper primarily to result from the interaction between formal and informal institutions. As such, an asymmetry between the laws and regulations and the socially shared unwritten norms results in low tax morale.

Evaluating the influence of formal institutions on tax morale, the first policy lesson is related to the limitations of the rational economic actor model. As previous studies show, increasing the level of deterrents produces inconclusive results ( Torgler, 2003a, 2005a, c ; Torgler and Werner, 2005 ; Torgler et al. , 2007a, 2010 ; Williams and Horodnic, 2016c ) and might lead rather to lower tax morale and, consequently, lower tax compliance. Therefore, governments can use other measures beyond enforcement for improving citizens’ tax morale and, consequently, their tax compliance.

Hence, measures for changing the formal institutions are required. As such, measures are needed not only for modernising government and for improving the structural economic and social conditions but also for building trust in public authorities. An extensive body of literature shows that tax morale is low, with low trust in various public authorities (i.e. government, parliament, courts and legal system, tax authority, etc.). Furthermore, the perceived fairness and effectiveness of the government spending as well as the perceived level of corruption shape the tax morale. As such, measures aimed to improve the social contract between governments and citizens and to foster the horizontal trust are necessary. This requires improvements in procedural justice (i.e. citizens are treated in a respectful, impartial and responsible manner by the tax authority, shifting away from a “cops and robbers” approach), procedural fairness (citizens perceive that the share they pay is fair in comparison with the share paid by others) and redistributive justice (citizens believe that they receive the goods and services they deserve according to the paid taxes) ( Kirchgässner, 2010 ; Molero and Pujol, 2012 ; Murphy, 2005 ; Williams and Horodnic, 2015a ).

Second, informal institutions are proven to shape tax morale as well, and measures aimed to alter informal institutions are thus required. As long as paying taxes owed does not represent a socially accepted norm, tax morale will be low. However, the results from previous studies show that governments have the capacity to influence social norms. As such, the governments can improve the transparency of public spending, can use awareness raising campaigns for providing information on what public goods and services are paid from taxes or can encourage tax education. For example, a study in UK shows that sending letters reminding the taxpayers how their taxes contribute to the public goods leads to a decrease in delaying tax payments ( Hallsworth et al. , 2017 ). Similarly, a study conducted in Turkey and Spain shows that tax education in universities has a positive effect on the level of tax morale ( Goksu and Sahpaz, 2015 ).

As a lack of trust in other taxpayers and the perception that tax evasion is widespread in a society negatively affects tax morale, measures aimed at fostering horizontal trust are also required. This can be achieved, for example, by providing to citizens’ information about their peers’ behaviour ( Luttmer and Singhal, 2014 ). For example, a study conducted in the UK investigated whether different messages about the peers’ behaviour influence timely payments ( Hallsworth et al. , 2017 ). Three different messages were included in the study, namely, “nine out of ten people pay their tax on time”, “nine out of ten people in the UK pay their tax on time” or “nine out of ten in the UK pay their tax on time. You are currently in the very small minority of people who have not paid us yet”. All three messages proved to have a positive effect on timely payments with the highest effect for the third message which underlines that the individual falls in the minority of those non-compliant.

In sum, this paper has outlined the influence of formal and informal institutions on tax morale as well as the socio-demographic characteristics of those displaying low/high tax morale. Thus, by synthesising and structuring the factors that shape tax morale, the paper provides a useful tool for both researchers and policy makers. Researchers can easily acknowledge what was investigated so far in the field and the type of methods and data. For policy makers, the paper provides not only an overview of the population groups more susceptible to low tax morale, who therefore, can be targeted in future campaigns, but also the type of policy measures and narratives that are more likely to enhance tax morale. If governments start recognising that low tax morale and consequently high tax non-compliance arise when a gap exists between formal and informal institutions and begin exploring policy measures to reduce this gap, rather than persisting with deterrence measures, then this paper will have achieved its objective.

6. Directions for future research

As shown in this paper, in the past decades, a large number of studies have focussed on understanding tax morale and its role in tax compliance. However, the vast majority are based on cross-sectional analyses. Considering that tax morale and the individuals’ willingness to comply can change over time ( Torgler, 2002a ), more longitudinal analyses would enable researchers to measure how different policy measures shape tax morale and how tax morale is altered by these measures.

Formal and informal institutions are influencing each other. Not only the government can use measures to alter formal institutions in a positive way for improving tax morale and tax compliance, but so too can citizens influence state morale by electing and voting officials that closer express their views and expectations on formal institutions. As such, investigating the interaction effects between formal and informal institutions in shaping the tax morale might lead to new important insights. Chan et al . (2018) made a step in this direction by analysing the interaction effects between vertical and horizontal trust in 108 countries. The results reveal a multiplier effect of trust on tax morale: “horizontal trust breeds vertical trust and vice versa” and shows that horizontal trust (measured as generalised trust), varies under different levels of vertical trust and structural conditions ( Chan et al. , 2018 ). Future studies to better understand this should now be undertaken.

Finally, the vast majority of studies on tax morale and tax compliance have used surveys or laboratory experiments. Rather recently, a few studies (see e.g. Hallsworth, 2014 ; Hallsworth et al. , 2017 ) have started to use field experiments in collaboration with the tax authorities. This approach not only creates a bridge between the research results and the design of policy measures but also eliminates the shortcomings of the artificial conditions created in laboratory experiments and enables us to observe the direct effect of a specific policy measure.

Formal institutions and vertical trust

Variable Result Study
Trust in public authorities A high trust in public authorities is associated with high tax morale , , . (2018), . (2012), , . (2013), , . (2015), , . (2016), , , , , , . (2013), , , , , . (2007a, b, 2008, 2010), , . (2017)
Government quality/spending effectiveness Higher perceived quality/effectiveness of spending is associated with higher tax morale . (2016), , , , , , . (2017)
Government fairness (including fairness of tax system) The higher the perceived fairness of the government, the higher the tax morale . (2016), , , . (2016), . (2005, 2009), , , , . (2008), . (2017)
Deterrence measures No relationship with tax morale , . (2010)
High risk of detection/expected sanctions associated with higher tax morale , . (2007a),
GDP/ GNP Positive impact on tax morale/ positive correlated , . (2012), ,
Government expenditure (i.e. social protection, education, health) Positive impact on tax morale , , ,
Inflation Negative impact on tax morale
Tax rate The higher the tax rate, the lower the tax morale. Progressive tax systems improve tax morale . (2016), , , , , , . (2007b), ,
Income inequality (Gini index) Negative correlated with tax morale . (2012), , ,
Corruption Wider corruption is associated with lower tax morale . (2016), . (2012), , , . (2008), ,
Democracy/responsive regulation/legal rights Direct democracy leads to higher tax morale , , , , . (2015), , , . (2007b, 2010),
Centralisation Centralisation induces lower tax morale.
Local autonomy has a significantly positive effect on tax morale and the size of the shadow economy
. (2005), , . (2010), , , . (2007b, 2010)
Level of immigration Higher immigration/immigrants associated with higher tax morale ,

Informal institutions and horizontal trust

Variable Result Study
Culture Culture has impact on tax morale. There are cultural differences within and between countries influencing tax morale , , , , . (2008), , , , c, 2005b, 2012),
National pride/patriotism Higher pride in national origin is associated with higher tax morale , . (2016), , , , , . (2013), , ,
Religion No difference in tax morale between different religions . (2016), ,
Higher religious values/high attendance to church are associated with higher tax morale , , , . (2012), , . (2008), , , , , , . (2015), , . (2007a, b, 2010), , . (2017)
Sense of community A stronger sense of community fosters tax morale , ,
Community size Those living in larger areas have lower tax morale ,
Those living in rural areas have a lower tax morale , , b),
Civic participation, social responsibility Positively associated with tax morale , , , . (2016), , . (2013), , , ,
Political participation and the intensity of discussing political matters with friends and family have negative effects on tax morale . (2015), , , . (2008)
Social stigma The social disapproval (social stigma) rise the tax morale , , . (2017)
Trust in other taxpayers A high trust in other taxpayers is associated with high tax morale , . (2016), , , , . (2008),
Perception of tax fraud/evasion (size) The higher the tax evasion is perceived, the lower the tax morale , , , ,

Socio-demographic characteristics and personal values/norms

Variable Result Study
Gender Women have higher tax morale than men , . (2018), . (2016), , , , , , , . (2010), , , , , , , . (2007a, b, 2008), , c), ,
Age Older people have higher tax morale . (2016), , , , , , . (2018), . (2012), , , 2008, . (2013), , , . (2016), , , , , , , . (2013), , , , . (2007a), , . (2017), , ,
Marital Status Married people have higher tax morale than singles , . (2018), , , , 2008, , , , , . (2007b), . (2017), , ,
Financial/economic status Higher satisfaction with financial situation is correlated with higher tax morale . (2016), , , , . (2013), . (2015), . (2016), , , , . (2013), , . (2007b), , , ,
Social class Higher economic class is associated with lower tax morale , , ,
Life satisfaction Individual’s life satisfaction increases tax morale , . (2015),
Employment status Self-employed persons have lower tax morale than employees , . (2018), . (2012), , , . (2013), , , , , . (2007a),
Part-time employees, unemployed people and students have lower tax morale than full-time employees . (2012), ,
Pensioners/retired have higher tax morale relative to non-pensioners . (2016), , , 2008, , , , . (2017)
Housewives/housekeepers have lower tax morale . (2015),
Those engaged in undeclared work have lower tax morale , , c ,
Education Better educated persons have higher tax morale . (2016), , , . (2016), . (2012), , . (2013), , , , , . (2007b), ,
Support for democracy Support for democratic values is associated with high tax morale . (2012), , , ,
Moral norms Personal integrity increases tax morale , , . (2013),
Individuals’ aversion to ethnic diversity Higher aversion to ethnic diversity is associated with lower tax morale . (2018)

Alasfour , F. , Samy , M. and Bampton , R. ( 2016 ), “ The determinants of tax morale and tax compliance: evidence from Jordan ”, in Hasseldine , J. (Ed.), Advances in Taxation , Emerald Group Publishing , Bingley , pp. 125 - 171 .

Allingham , M.G. and Sandmo , A. ( 1972 ), “ Income tax evasion: a theoretical analysis ”, Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 1 Nos 3-4 , pp. 323 - 338 .

Alm , J. and Gomez , J.L. ( 2008 ), “ Social capital and tax morale in Spain ”, Economic Analysis and Policy , Vol. 38 No. 1 , pp. 73 - 87 .

Alm , J. and Torgler , B. ( 2004 ), “ Estimating the determinants of tax morale ”, Proceedings: Annual Conference on Taxation and Minutes of the Annual Meeting of the National Tax Association , Vol. 97 , pp. 269 - 274 .

Alm , J. and Torgler , B. ( 2006 ), “ Culture differences and tax morale in the United States and in Europe ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 27 No. 2 , pp. 224 - 246 .

Andriani , L. ( 2016 ), “ Tax morale and prosocial behaviour: evidence from a Palestinian survey ”, Cambridge Journal of Economics , Vol. 40 No. 3 , pp. 821 - 841 .

Barone , G. and Mocetti , S. ( 2011 ), “ Tax morale and public spending inefficiency ”, International Tax and Public Finance , Vol. 18 No. 6 , pp. 724 - 749 .

Baumol , W.J. and Blinder , A. ( 2008 ), Macroeconomics: Principles and Policy , South-Western Publishing , Cincinnati, OH .

Belmonte , A. , Dell’Anno , R. and Teobaldelli , D. ( 2018 ), “ Tax morale, aversion to ethnic diversity, and decentralization ”, European Journal of Political Economy , available at: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.12.004

Bilgin , C. ( 2014 ), “ Determinants of tax morale in Spain and Turkey: an empirical analysis ”, European Journal of Government and Economics , Vol. 3 No. 1 , pp. 60 - 74 .

Braithwaite , V. and Ahmed , E. ( 2005 ), “ A threat to tax morale: the case of Australian higher education policy ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 26 No. 4 , pp. 523 - 540 .

Brink , W.D. and Porcano , T.M. ( 2016 ), “ The impact of culture and economic structure on tax morale and tax evasion: a country-level analysis using SEM ”, in Hasseldine , J. (Ed.), Advances in Taxation (Advances in Taxation, Vol. 23 , Emerald Group Publishing , Bingley , pp. 87 - 123 .

Çevik , S. ( 2016 ), “ Tax morale and tax compliance in socio-political context ”, in Aydin , M. and Tan , S.S. (Eds), Political Economy of Taxation , IJOPEC Publication , Istanbul , pp. 37 - 57 .

Chan , H.F. , Supriyadi , M.W. and Torgler , B. ( 2018 ), “ Trust and tax morale ”, in Uslaner , E.M. (Ed.), The Oxford Handbook of Social and Political Trust , Oxford University Press , New York, NY , pp. 1 - 71 , available at: www.oxfordhandbooks.com/view/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780190274801.001.0001/oxfordhb-9780190274801-e-23 (accessed 20 January 2018 ).

Cullis , J.G. and Lewis , A. ( 1997 ), “ Why people pay taxes: from a conventional economic model to a model of social convention ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 18 Nos 2-3 , pp. 305 - 321 .

Cummings , R.G. , Martinez-Vazquez , J. , McKee , M. and Torgler , B. ( 2005 ), “ Effects of tax morale on tax compliance: experimental and survey evidence ”, available at: https://leitner.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/resources/docs/botswana.pdf (accessed 10 January 2018 ).

Cummings , R.G. , Martinez-Vazquez , J. , McKee , M. and Torgler , B. ( 2009 ), “ Tax morale affects tax compliance: evidence from surveys and an artefactual field experiment ”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization , Vol. 70 No. 3 , pp. 447 - 457 .

Cyan , M.R. , Koumpias , A.M. and Martinez-Vazquez , J. ( 2016 ), “ The determinants of tax morale in Pakistan ”, Journal of Asian Economics , Vol. 47 , pp. 23 - 34 .

D’Attoma , J. ( 2015 ), “ A nation divided: assessing the regional effects of institutions, social capital, and civic culture on tax morale in Italy ”, Dissertation thesis, University of Missouri-St Louis, St Louis, MO, July .

Daude , C. , Gutiérrez , H. and Melguizo , Á. ( 2012 ), “ What drives tax morale? ”, Working Paper No. 35, OECD Development Centre, Paris .

Dell’Anno , R. ( 2009 ), “ Tax evasion, tax morale and policy maker’s effectiveness ”, The Journal of Socio-Economics , Vol. 38 No. 6 , pp. 988 - 997 .

Doerrenberg , P. and Peichl , A. ( 2010 ), “ Progressive taxation and tax morale ”, IZA Discussion Paper No. 5378, The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn, December .

Dwenger , N. , Kleven , H. , Rasul , I. and Rincke , J. ( 2016 ), “ Extrinsic and intrinsic motivations for tax compliance: evidence from a field experiment in Germany ”, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy , Vol. 8 No. 3 , pp. 203 - 232 .

Feld , L.P. and Frey , B.S. ( 2004 ), “ Illegal, immoral, fattening or what? How deterrence and responsive regulation shape tax morale ”, Marburg Working Papers on Economics 200426, Faculty of Business Administration and Economics, Department of Economics, Philipps-Universität Marburg, Marburg .

Feld , L.P. and Frey , B.S. ( 2006 ), “ Tax evasion in Switzerland: the roles of deterrence and tax morale ”, Working Paper No. 284, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Zurich, April .

Feld , L.P. and Torgler , B. ( 2007 ), “ Tax morale after the reunification of Germany: results from a quasi-natural experiment ”, CESifo Working Paper No. 1921, CESifo Group, Munich .

Feld , L.P. , Torgler , B. and Dong , B. ( 2008 ), “ Coming closer? Tax morale, deterrence and social learning after German unification ”, Working Paper No. 2008-9, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Filippin , A. , Fiorio , C.V. and Viviano , E. ( 2013 ), “ The effect of tax enforcement on tax morale ”, European Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 32 , pp. 320 - 331 .

Frey , B.S. ( 2003 ), “ Deterrence and tax morale in the European Union ”, European Review , Vol. 11 No. 3 , pp. 385 - 406 .

Frey , B.S. and Torgler , B. ( 2007 ), “ Tax morale and conditional cooperation ”, Journal of Comparative Economics , Vol. 35 No. 1 , pp. 136 - 159 .

Gerstenbluth , M. , Melgar , N. , Pagano , J.P. and Rossi , M. ( 2012 ), “ How do inequality affect tax morale in Latin America and Caribbean? ”, Revista de Economia del Rosario , Vol. 15 No. 2 , pp. 123 - 135 .

Goksu , G.G. and Sahpaz , K.I. ( 2015 ), “ Comparison of tax morale of Turkish and Spanish higher education students: the samples of Sakarya university and the university of Zaragoza ”, Procedia – Social and Behavioral Sciences , Vol. 186 , pp. 222 - 230 .

Güth , W. , Levati , V. and Sausgruber , R. ( 2005 ), “ Tax morale and (de-)centralization: an experimental study ”, Public Choice , Vol. 125 Nos 1-2 , pp. 171 - 188 .

Halla , M. ( 2012 ), “ Tax morale and compliance behavior: first evidence on a causal link ”, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy , Vol. 12 No. 1 , pp. 1 - 27 .

Hallsworth , M. ( 2014 ), “ The use of field experiments to increase tax compliance ”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy , Vol. 30 No. 4 , pp. 658 - 679 .

Hallsworth , M. , List , J.A. , Metcalfe , R.D. and Vlaev , I. ( 2017 ), “ The behavioralist as tax collector: using natural field experiments to enhance tax compliance ”, Journal of Public Economics , Vol. 148 , pp. 14 - 31 .

Helmke , G. and Levitsky , S. ( 2004 ), “ Informal institutions and comparative politics: a research agenda ”, Perspectives on Politics , Vol. 2 No. 4 , pp. 725 - 740 .

Horodnic , A.V. and Williams , C.C. ( 2018 ), “ Informal payments by patients for health services: prevalence and determinants ”, The Service Industries Journal , Vol. 38 Nos 11-12 , pp. 841 - 855 , available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02642069.2018.1450870

Horodnic , I.A. and Williams , C.C. ( 2016 ), “ An evaluation of the shadow economy in Baltic States: a tax morale perspective ”, International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business , Vol. 28 Nos 2-3 , pp. 339 - 358 .

Ibrahim , M. , Musah , A. and Abdul-Hanan , A. ( 2015 ), “ Beyond enforcement: what drives tax morale in Ghana? ”, Humanomics , Vol. 31 No. 4 , pp. 399 - 414 .

Jahnke , B. ( 2015 ), “ How does petty corruption affect tax morale in sub-Saharan Africa? An empirical analysis ”, Hannover Economic Papers (HEP) dp-564, Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Fakultät, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Hannover .

Kanniainen , V. and Pääkkönen , J. ( 2010 ), “ Do the catholic and protestant countries differ by their tax morale? ”, Empirica , Vol. 37 No. 3 , pp. 271 - 290 .

Kirchgässner , G. ( 2010 ), “ Tax morale, tax evasion, and the shadow economy ”, Discussion Paper No. 2010-17, Department of Economics, University of St Gallen, St Gallen, May .

Kirchler , E. , Muehlbacher , S. , Kastlunger , B. and Wahl , I. ( 2007 ), “ Why pay taxes? A review of tax compliance decisions ”, International Studies Program Working Paper No. 07-30, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA, December .

Kondelaji , M.H. , Sameti , M. , Amiri , H. and Moayedfar , R. ( 2016 ), “ Analyzing determinants of tax morale based on social psychology theory: case study of Iran ”, Iranian Economic Review , Vol. 20 No. 4 , pp. 581 - 598 .

Kountouris , Y. and Remoundou , K. ( 2013 ), “ Is there a cultural component in tax morale? Evidence from immigrants in Europe ”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization , Vol. 96 , pp. 104 - 119 .

Lago-Peñas , I. and Lago-Peñas , S. ( 2010 ), “ The determinants of tax morale in comparative perspective: evidence from European countries ”, European Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 26 No. 4 , pp. 441 - 453 .

Leonardo , G. and Martinez-Vazquez , J. ( 2016 ), “ Politicians, bureaucrats, and tax morale: what shapes tax compliance attitudes? ”, International Studies Program Working Paper No. 16-08, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA, August .

Leonardo , G.M. ( 2011 ), “ Politics and tax morale. The role of trust, values, and beliefs, in shaping individual attitudes towards tax compliance ”, dissertation thesis, Georgia Institute of Technology, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA, December .

Li , S.X. ( 2010 ), “ Social identities, ethnic diversity, and tax morale ”, Public Finance Review , Vol. 38 No. 2 , pp. 146 - 177 .

Lima , F.W.S. and Zaklan , G. ( 2008 ), “ A multi-agent-based approach to tax morale ”, International Journal of Modern Physics C , Vol. 19 No. 12 , pp. 1797 - 1808 .

Lisi , G. ( 2015 ), “ Tax morale, tax compliance and the optimal tax policy ”, Economic Analysis and Policy , Vol. 45 , pp. 27 - 32 .

Long , S. and Swingen , J. ( 1991 ), “ The conduct of tax-evasion experiments: validation, analytical methods, and experimental Realism ”, in Webley , P. , Robben , H. , Elffers , H. and Hessing , D. (Eds), Tax Evasion: An Experimental Approach , Cambridge University Press , Cambridge , pp. 128 - 138 .

Lubian , D. and Zarri , L. ( 2011 ), “ Happiness and tax morale: an empirical analysis ”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization , Vol. 80 No. 1 , pp. 223 - 243 .

Luttmer , E.F.P. and Singhal , M. ( 2014 ), “ Tax morale ”, Journal of Economic Perspectives , Vol. 28 No. 4 , pp. 149 - 168 .

McKerchar , M. , Bloomquist , K. and Pope , J. ( 2013 ), “ Indicators of tax morale: an exploratory study ”, eJournal of Tax Research , Vol. 11 No. 1 , pp. 5 - 22 .

MacGregor , J. and Wilkinson , B. ( 2012 ), “ The effect of economic patriotism on tax morale and attitudes toward tax compliance ”, in Stock , T. (Ed.), Advances in Taxation (Advances in Taxation, Vol. 20) , Emerald Group Publishing , Bingley , pp. 159 - 180 .

Maria-Dolores , R. , Alarcón , C. and Garre , M.E. ( 2010 ), “ Tax morale in Spain: a study into some of its principal determinants ”, Journal of Economic Issues , Vol. 44 No. 4 , pp. 855 - 876 .

Martinez-Vazquez , J. and Torgler , B. ( 2009 ), “ The evolution of tax morale in modern Spain ”, Journal of Economic Issues , Vol. 43 No. 1 , pp. 1 - 28 .

Martins , A. and Gomes , C. ( 2014 ), “ Tax morale, occupation and income level: an analysis of Portuguese taxpayers ”, Journal of Economics, Business and Management , Vol. 2 No. 2 , pp. 112 - 116 .

Molero , J.C. and Pujol , F. ( 2012 ), “ Walking inside the potential tax evader’s mind: tax morale does matter ”, Journal of Business Ethics , Vol. 105 No. 2 , pp. 151 - 162 .

Murphy , K. ( 2005 ), “ Regulating more effectively: the relationship between procedural justice, legitimacy and tax non-compliance ”, Journal of Law and Society , Vol. 32 No. 4 , pp. 562 - 589 .

Niesiobędzka , M. ( 2014 ), “ Relations between procedural fairness, tax morale, institutional trust and tax evasion ”, Journal of Social Research & Policy , Vol. 5 No. 1 , pp. 41 - 52 .

Nordblom , K. and Žamac , J. ( 2012 ), “ Endogenous norm formation over the life cycle – the case of tax morale ”, Economic Analysis & Policy , Vol. 42 No. 2 , pp. 153 - 170 .

North , D.C. ( 1990 ), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance , Cambridge University Press , Cambridge .

Pommerehne , W.W. and Frey , B.S. ( 1992 ), “ The effects of tax administration on tax morale ”, Discussion Papers Series II 191, University of Konstanz, Konstanz, September .

Ristovska , M. , Mojsoska-Blazevski , N. and Nikolov , M. ( 2013 ), “ An alternative view to the tax evasion: the effect of tax morale on paying taxes in Macedonia and EU countries ”, Serbian Journal of Management , Vol. 8 No. 2 , pp. 169 - 183 .

Rodriguez-Justicia , D. and Theilen , B. ( 2018 ), “ Education and tax morale ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 64 , pp. 18 - 48 .

Russo , F.F. ( 2013 ), “ Tax morale and tax evasion reports ”, Economics Letters , Vol. 121 No. 1 , pp. 110 - 114 .

Sá , C. , Martins , A. and Gomes , C. ( 2015 ), “ Tax morale determinants in Portugal ”, European Scientific Journal , ESJ August 2015 Special Edition , pp. 236 - 254 , available at: www.eujournal.org/index.php/esj/issue/view/198

Saitta , P. ( 2017 ), “ Practices of subjectivity: the informal economies and the subaltern rebellion ”, International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy , Vol. 37 No. 7-8 , pp. 400 - 416 .

Schmӧlders , G. ( 1970 ), “ Survey research in public finance: a behavioural approach to fiscal theory ”, Public Finance , Vol. 25 No. 2 , pp. 300 - 306 .

Sipos , A. ( 2015 ), “ Determining factors of tax-morale with special emphasis on the tax revenues of local self-governments ”, Procedia Economics and Finance , Vol. 30 , pp. 758 - 767 .

Stark , J.A. and Kirchler , E. ( 2017 ), “ Inheritance tax compliance – earmarking with normative value principles ”, International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy , Vol. 37 Nos 7-8 , pp. 452 - 467 .

Steinmo , S. ( 2017 ), “ Trustworthy institutions: a cognitive theory of tax morale ”, available at: www.researchgate.net/publication/320289711_Trustworthy_Institutions_A_cognitive_theory_of_Tax_Morale (accessed 12 January 2018 ).

Strümpel , B. ( 1969 ), “ The contribution of survey research to public finance ”, in Peacock , A.T. (Ed.), Quantitative Analysis in Public Finance , Praeger Publishers , New York, NY , pp. 14 - 32 .

Sumartaya , D. and Hafidiah , A. ( 2014 ), “ The influence of taxpayer’s awareness and tax morale toward tax evasion ”, International Journal of Business, Economics and Law , Vol. 5 No. 1 , pp. 60 - 68 .

Torgler , B. ( 2001 ), “ What do we know about tax morale and tax compliance? ”, International Review of Economics and Business (RISEC) , Vol. 48 No. 3 , pp. 395 - 419 .

Torgler , B. ( 2002/2003 ), “ Does culture matter? Tax morale in an East-West-German comparison ”, FinanzArchiv/ Public Finance Analysis , Vol. 59 No. 4 , pp. 504 - 528 .

Torgler , B. ( 2002a ), “ Speaking to theorists and searching for facts: tax morale and tax compliance in experiments ”, Journal of Economic Surveys , Vol. 16 No. 5 , pp. 657 - 683 .

Torgler , B. ( 2002b ), “ Vertical and exchange equity in a tax morale experiment ”, available at: https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/b5c9/10008f223980fdd77ab23a7a878c0bbadf9b.pdf (accessed 10 January 2018 ).

Torgler , B. ( 2003a ), “ Tax morale and institutions ”, Working Paper No. 2003-09, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Torgler , B. ( 2003b ), “ Tax morale in transition countries ”, Post-Communist Economies , Vol. 15 No. 3 , pp. 357 - 381 .

Torgler , B. ( 2003c ), “ Tax morale, rule-governed behaviour and trust ”, Constitutional Political Economy , Vol. 14 No. 2 , pp. 119 - 140 .

Torgler , B. ( 2003d ), “ To evade taxes or not to evade: that is the question ”, Journal of Socio-Economics , Vol. 32 No. 3 , pp. 283 - 302 .

Torgler , B. ( 2004a ), “ Cross-culture comparison of tax morale and tax compliance: evidence from Costa Rica and Switzerland ”, International Journal of Comparative Sociology , Vol. 45 Nos 1-2 , pp. 17 - 43 .

Torgler , B. ( 2004b ), “ Tax morale in Asian countries ”, Journal of Asian Economics , Vol. 15 , pp. 237 - 266 .

Torgler , B. ( 2004c ), “ Tax morale, trust and corruption: empirical evidence from transition countries ”, Working Paper No. 2004-05, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Torgler , B. ( 2005a ), “ A knight without a sword? The effects of audit courts on tax morale ”, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE) , Vol. 161 No. 4 , pp. 735 - 760 .

Torgler , B. ( 2005b ), “ Tax morale in Latin America ”, Public Choice , Vol. 122 Nos 1-2 , pp. 133 - 157 .

Torgler , B. ( 2005c ), “ Tax morale and direct democracy ”, European Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 21 No. 2 , pp. 525 - 531 .

Torgler , B. ( 2006 ), “ The importance of faith: tax morale and religiosity ”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization , Vol. 61 No. 1 , pp. 81 - 109 .

Torgler , B. ( 2007 ), Tax Compliance and Morale: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis , Edward Elgar , Cheltenham .

Torgler , B. ( 2011 ), “ Tax morale and compliance review of evidence and case studies for Europe ”, Policy Research Working Paper No. 5922, The World Bank, Europe and Central Asia Region, December .

Torgler , B. ( 2012 ), “ Tax morale, Eastern Europe and European enlargement ”, Communist and Post-Communist Studies , Vol. 45 Nos 1-2 , pp. 11 - 25 .

Torgler , B. and Murphy , K. ( 2004 ), “ Tax morale in Australia: what shapes it and has it changed over time? ”, Journal of Australian Taxation , Vol. 7 No. 2 , pp. 298 - 335 .

Torgler , B. and Schaffner , M. ( 2007 ), “ Causes and consequences of tax morale: an empirical investigation ”, Working Paper No. 2007-11, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Torgler , B. and Schneider , F. ( 2004 ), “ Does culture influence tax morale? Evidence from different European countries ”, Working Paper No. 2004-17, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Torgler , B. and Schneider , F. ( 2006 ), “ Shadow economy, institutions, and tax morale ”, Proceedings: Annual Conference on Taxation and Minutes of the Annual Meeting of the National Tax Association , Vol. 99 , pp. 204 - 210 .

Torgler , B. and Schneider , F. ( 2007a ), “ What shapes attitudes toward paying taxes? Evidence from multicultural European countries ”, Social Science Quarterly , Vol. 88 No. 2 , pp. 443 - 470 .

Torgler , B. and Schneider , F. ( 2007b ), “ Shadow economy, tax morale, governance and institutional quality: a panel analysis ”, IZA Discussion Paper No. 2563, The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn, January .

Torgler , B. and Schneider , F. ( 2009 ), “ The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy ”, Journal of Economic Psychology , Vol. 30 No. 2 , pp. 228 - 245 .

Torgler , B. and Werner , J. ( 2005 ), “ Fiscal autonomy and tax morale: evidence from Germany ”, Working Paper No. 2005-07, Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, Basel .

Torgler , B. , Demir , I.C. , Macintyre , A. and Schaffner , M. ( 2008 ), “ Causes and consequences of tax morale: an empirical investigation ”, Economic Analysis and Policy , Vol. 38 No. 2 , pp. 313 - 339 .

Torgler , B. , Schaffner , M. and Macintyre , A. ( 2007a ), “ Tax compliance, tax compliance, tax morale, and governance quality ”, International Studies Program Working Paper No. 07-27, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA, December .

Torgler , B. , Schneider , F. and Schaltegger , C.A. ( 2007b ), “ With or against the people? The impact of a bottom-up approach on tax morale and the shadow economy ”, Working/Discussion Paper No. 211, QUT – School of Economics and Finance, Brisbane, February .

Torgler , B. , Schneider , F. and Schaltegger , C.A. ( 2010 ), “ Local autonomy, tax morale, and the shadow economy ”, Public Choice , Vol. 144 Nos 1-2 , pp. 293 - 321 .

Trüdinger , E.-M. and Hildebrandt , A. ( 2013 ), “ Causes and contexts of tax morale: rational considerations, community orientations, and communist rule ”, International Political Science Review , Vol. 34 No. 2 , pp. 191 - 209 .

Vythelingum , P. , Soondram’ , H. and Jugurnath , B. ( 2017 ), “ An assessment of tax morale among Mauritian taxpayers ”, Journal of Accounting and Taxation , Vol. 9 No. 1 , pp. 1 - 10 .

Williams , C.C. ( 2014 ), Confronting the Shadow Economy: Evaluating Tax Compliance and Behaviour Policies , Edward Elgar , Cheltenham .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , A.V. ( 2017 ), “ Rethinking informal payments by patients in Europe: an institutional approach ”, Health Policy , Vol. 121 No. 10 , pp. 1053 - 1062 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , A.V. ( 2018 ), “ Explaining informal payments for health services in Central and Eastern Europe: an institutional asymmetry perspective ”, Post-Communist Economies , Vol. 30 No. 4 , pp. 440 - 458 , available at: https://doi.org/10.1080/14631377.2018.1442051

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2015a ), “ Evaluating the prevalence of the undeclared economy in Central and Eastern Europe: an institutional asymmetry perspective ”, European Journal of Industrial Relations , Vol. 21 No. 4 , pp. 389 - 406 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2015b ), “ Explaining and tackling envelope wages in the Baltic Sea region: an institutional perspective ”, Baltic Journal of Management , Vol. 10 No. 3 , pp. 295 - 312 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2015c ), “ Explaining and tackling the shadow economy in Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania: a tax morale approach ”, Baltic Journal of Economics , Vol. 15 No. 2 , pp. 81 - 98 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2015d ), “ Explaining the prevalence of illegitimate wage practices in Southern Europe: an institutional analysis ”, South European Society and Politics , Vol. 20 No. 2 , pp. 203 - 221 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2015e ), “ Tackling the informal economy in Southeast Europe: an institutional approach ”, Southeast European and Black Sea Studies , Vol. 15 No. 4 , pp. 519 - 539 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2016a ), “ An institutional theory of the informal economy: some lessons from the United Kingdom ”, International Journal of Social Economics , Vol. 43 No. 7 , pp. 722 - 738 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2016b ), “ Cross-country variations in the participation of small businesses in the informal economy: an institutional asymmetry explanation ”, Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development , Vol. 23 No. 1 , pp. 3 - 24 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2016c ), “ Tackling the undeclared economy in the European Union: an evaluation of the tax morale approach ”, Industrial Relations Journal , Vol. 47 No. 4 , pp. 322 - 340 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2017a ), “ Evaluating the illegal employer practice of under-reporting employees’ salaries ”, British Journal of Industrial Relations , Vol. 55 No. 1 , pp. 83 - 111 .

Williams , C.C. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2017b ), “ Explaining the informal economy in post-communist societies: a study of the asymmetry between formal and informal institutions in Romania ”, in Polese , A. , Williams , C.C. , Horodnic , I.A. and Bejakovic , P. (Eds), The Informal Economy in Global Perspective – Varieties of Governance , Palgrave Macmillan , Cham , pp. 117 - 140 .

Williams , C.C. and Krasniqi , B. ( 2017 ), “ Evaluating the individual- and country-level variations in tax morale: evidence from 35 Eurasian countries ”, Journal of Economic Studies , Vol. 44 No. 5 , pp. 816 - 832 .

Williams , C.C. and Martinez , Á. ( 2014 ), “ Explaining cross-national variations in tax morality in the European Union: an exploratory analysis ”, Studies of Transition States and Societies , Vol. 6 No. 1 , pp. 5 - 18 .

Windebank , J. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2016 ), “ Explaining participation in informal employment: a social contract perspective ”, International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business , Vol. 28 Nos 2-3 , pp. 178 - 194 .

Windebank , J. and Horodnic , I.A. ( 2017 ), “ Explaining participation in undeclared work in France: lessons for policy evaluation ”, International Journal of Sociology and Social Policy , Vol. 37 Nos 3-4 , pp. 203 - 217 .

Acknowledgements

This paper is part of a project that has received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme under the Marie Skłodowska-Curie grant agreement No. 746358.

Corresponding author

About the author.

Dr Ioana Alexandra Horodnic is Marie Sklodowska Curie Fellow at the University of Sheffield in the United Kingdom. Her research interests are in labour economics and the undeclared economy. She has published some 40 journal articles and book chapters over the past three years focussing on: the supply of undeclared work, structural drivers of undeclared work, envelope wages, demand for undeclared goods and services, and evaluating policy approaches towards undeclared work.

Related articles

All feedback is valuable.

Please share your general feedback

Report an issue or find answers to frequently asked questions

Contact Customer Support

  • Search Menu

Sign in through your institution

  • Advance Articles
  • Author Guidelines
  • Submission Site
  • Open Access
  • Self-Archiving Policy
  • Why Submit?
  • About Communication Theory
  • About International Communication Association
  • Editorial Board
  • Advertising & Corporate Services
  • Journals Career Network
  • Journals on Oxford Academic
  • Books on Oxford Academic

Criticism in opposition: review of Epistemology of Communication in Brazil: critical essays on theory of science , by Francisco Rüdiger

ORCID logo

  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data

Arthur F Simões Pires, Criticism in opposition: review of Epistemology of Communication in Brazil: critical essays on theory of science , by Francisco Rüdiger, Communication Theory , 2024;, qtae014, https://doi.org/10.1093/ct/qtae014

  • Permissions Icon Permissions

Started about a decade ago, Francisco Rüdiger has developed a contestation project in relation to the work of a group of Brazilian communicologists which, in 2022, is sanctioned in the work Epistemologia da Comunicação no Brasil: ensaios críticos sobre teoria da ciência [ Epistemology of Communication in Brazil: critical essays on science theory ]. Particularities aside, the author disagrees, to begin with, with a fundamental conception: that Communication is an autonomous science. Divergent from the doctrinal action undertaken by those who would be the epistemologists of the area, Rüdiger argues that, observing the empirical evidence, based on a vast literature of different traditions, there is neither vocation nor will of the scientific exercise. He takes into account the fact that, in the case of the student body, in a historical perspective, there is a greater concern with the demands of the market—and this same market also does not give evidence of appreciation of space and scientific activity—so, the profile of the courses (such as Journalism, Advertising & Propaganda, Audiovisual Production/Cinema, Public Relations, and so on and so forth) consolidated as a technical-professional profile; not an erudite, or scholar one.

International Communication Association

International Communication Association members

Personal account.

  • Sign in with email/username & password
  • Get email alerts
  • Save searches
  • Purchase content
  • Activate your purchase/trial code
  • Add your ORCID iD

Institutional access

Sign in with a library card.

  • Sign in with username/password
  • Recommend to your librarian
  • Institutional account management
  • Get help with access

Access to content on Oxford Academic is often provided through institutional subscriptions and purchases. If you are a member of an institution with an active account, you may be able to access content in one of the following ways:

IP based access

Typically, access is provided across an institutional network to a range of IP addresses. This authentication occurs automatically, and it is not possible to sign out of an IP authenticated account.

Choose this option to get remote access when outside your institution. Shibboleth/Open Athens technology is used to provide single sign-on between your institution’s website and Oxford Academic.

  • Click Sign in through your institution.
  • Select your institution from the list provided, which will take you to your institution's website to sign in.
  • When on the institution site, please use the credentials provided by your institution. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.
  • Following successful sign in, you will be returned to Oxford Academic.

If your institution is not listed or you cannot sign in to your institution’s website, please contact your librarian or administrator.

Enter your library card number to sign in. If you cannot sign in, please contact your librarian.

Society Members

Society member access to a journal is achieved in one of the following ways:

Sign in through society site

Many societies offer single sign-on between the society website and Oxford Academic. If you see ‘Sign in through society site’ in the sign in pane within a journal:

  • Click Sign in through society site.
  • When on the society site, please use the credentials provided by that society. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.

If you do not have a society account or have forgotten your username or password, please contact your society.

Sign in using a personal account

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members. See below.

A personal account can be used to get email alerts, save searches, purchase content, and activate subscriptions.

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members.

Viewing your signed in accounts

Click the account icon in the top right to:

  • View your signed in personal account and access account management features.
  • View the institutional accounts that are providing access.

Signed in but can't access content

Oxford Academic is home to a wide variety of products. The institutional subscription may not cover the content that you are trying to access. If you believe you should have access to that content, please contact your librarian.

For librarians and administrators, your personal account also provides access to institutional account management. Here you will find options to view and activate subscriptions, manage institutional settings and access options, access usage statistics, and more.

Short-term Access

To purchase short-term access, please sign in to your personal account above.

Don't already have a personal account? Register

Email alerts

Citing articles via.

  • Recommend to Your Librarian
  • Advertising and Corporate Services

Affiliations

  • Online ISSN 1468-2885
  • Copyright © 2024 International Communication Association
  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Rights and permissions
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright © 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

IMAGES

  1. Figure 1 from Literature Review of Enterprise Systems Research Using

    institutional theory literature review

  2. (PDF) Institutional Theory

    institutional theory literature review

  3. (PDF) Literature Review of Enterprise Systems Research Using

    institutional theory literature review

  4. Adoption and New Institutional Theory Literature Review

    institutional theory literature review

  5. Adoption and New Institutional Theory Literature Review

    institutional theory literature review

  6. (DOC) Institutional Theory: a Literature

    institutional theory literature review

COMMENTS

  1. Institutional Theory

    The framework of institutional theory is primarily concerned with an organization's relationship with the institutional environment ( Martinez and Dacin, 1999 ). Institutions are the 'rules of the game' in a society, including formal rules (political rules, economic rules, and contracts) and informal rules (codes of conduct, norms of ...

  2. Institutional Theory in Organization Studies

    Institutional theory is a prominent perspective in contemporary organizational research. It encompasses a large, diverse body of theoretical and empirical work connected by a common emphasis on cultural understandings and shared expectations. ... (2016). A review of the nonmarket strategy literature: Toward a multi-theoretical integration ...

  3. (PDF) An Institutional Theory Investigation: Analysis of the Main

    The present study aims to conduct a systematic review of the literature on Institutional Theory and innovation with a focus on investigating the respective trends and influences between the ...

  4. Institutional Theory

    The first stage in institutional theory is referred to as the "old" institutionalism - institutionalism that encompasses detailed qualitative case studies of organizations in the 1950s and 1960s (Suddaby 2013).In the old institutionalism, "issues of influence, coalitions, and competing values were central, along with power and informal structures" (Greenwood and Hinings 1996, p. 1022).

  5. An Intellectual History of Institutional Theory: Looking Back to Move

    The advancement and growth of institutional theory over the past seven decades has brought with it an increasing plurality in its theoretical and empirical approaches, along with a number of critiques about its coherence and impact. We address these critiques, and offer remedies for overcoming the perceived challenges. We begin by examining the intellectual history of institutional theory in ...

  6. Challenging Institutional Theory's Critical Credentials

    By attending to the social embeddedness of action, institutional theory delivers an antidote to analyses based on objectivist ontology that deliver an often mathematicized analysis of objectivated outcomes (Lawson, 2013).Whether in its 'realist' or more 'phenomenological' variants (Meyer, 2008), institutionalist analysis has addressed inter alia how actors' beliefs and actions are ...

  7. Institutional logics analysis in higher education research

    In a systematic literature review on the use of institutional theory in higher education, Cai and Mehari (Citation 2015) found that most higher education studies applying institutional theory refer to 'new' institutionalism with a focus on, for example, isomorphism and structuration processes, while more recently developed insights such as ...

  8. Institutional Theory

    Institutional theory is a theoretical framework for analyzing social (particularly organizational) phenomena, which views the social world as significantly comprised of institutions - enduring rules, practices, and structures that set conditions on action. Institutions are fundamental in explaining the social world because they are built into ...

  9. Why (and How) Institutional Theory Can Be Critical: Addressing the

    A gap year for institutional theory: Integrating the study of institutional work and participatory action research. Journal of Management Inquiry , 19, 305-316. Crossref

  10. Institutional theory and HRM: A new look

    Each broadly reflects the foundational understanding of institutional theory, consistent with the findings of the literature review. Both Wright and McMahan (1992) and Barringer and Milkovich (1998) introduce institutional theory to HRM scholarship in order to address a perceived theoretical lacuna in the field.

  11. The Diffusion and Use of Institutional Theory: A Cross-Disciplinary

    This study also serves to signpost cross-disciplinary research, and thus opens up a whole new research paradigm. Therefore, this article seeks to provide a bibliometric analysis and a comprehensive and systematic review of the literature pertaining to institutional theory to ascertain the current 'state of play' of the theory.

  12. The diffusion and use of institutional theory: a cross-disciplinary

    This study also serves to signpost cross-disciplinary research, and thus opens up a whole new research paradigm. Therefore, this article seeks to provide a bibliometric analysis and a comprehensive and systematic review of the literature pertaining to institutional theory to ascertain the current 'state of play' of the theory.

  13. (PDF) The Diffusion and Use of Institutional Theory: A Cross

    Information on a series of variables was extracted after conducting a review of 511 articles across various disciplines that have utilised institutional theory, published in 210 peer-reviewed ...

  14. Institutional theory‐based research on corporate social responsibility

    To review the institutional theory-based CSR literature, we developed a systematic protocol following similar literature reviews (e.g., Boiral et al., 2018; Fortis et al., 2018). First, we conducted a keyword search using the search engine EBSCO Host and journal-publishing websites Sage, Science Direct, Informs, and Emerald.

  15. When, why and how institutional change takes place: a systematic review

    A systematic literature review combines qualitative and quantitative methods to map the fields of study in a transparent manner. ... suggests that variants of institutional theory or their combinations (27 papers, 93%) are widely used. In addition to institutional theory, multiple-policy stream analysis (Kingdon, Citation 1995) in particular is ...

  16. Institutional Theory in Social Entrepreneurship: A Systematic Review

    Thus, a review of existing SE literature that employs institutional theory seems warranted and timely. Accordingly, we initially review the current use of institutional theory in SE research based on 101 peer-reviewed articles published between 2008 and 2020. More specifically, drawing on four critical institutional perspectives that have long ...

  17. Beyond Red Tape and Fools: Institutional Theory in Entrepreneurship

    In this review, we focus on three characteristics of the articles: institutional logic, level of analysis, and methodology. Further, we identify three distinct periods of EIn research: the conceptual phase, 1992-2000, the exploration phase 2001-2007, and the acceptance phase 2008-2014.

  18. PDF Literature Review of Enterprise Systems Research Using Institutional

    The focused literature review of institutional theory is based upon two seminal books about institutional theory: "The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis" (Powell and Di-Maggio 1991) and the three editions of "Institutions and Organizations" (Scott 1995; Scott 2001; Scott 2008b).

  19. A Systematic Literature Review of Theories Underpinning ...

    3.1.3 Institutional Theory. The institutional theory (Selznick, ... Our literature review finds that multi-theory articles are concentrated in the period between 2013 and 2019, while the most dated article traces back to Reverte and also represents the most cited paper.

  20. Full article: The use of institutional theory in social and

    A combination of search terms reflecting key themes in the SEA literature and institutional theory was used for all searches. Footnote 4 The main literature search was completed in February 2023, but we continuously kept our review updated to ensure that any additional relevant studies published after this date were included in our sample.

  21. PDF Some Issues In The Institutional Theory: A Critical Analysis

    the last part of the article, we will support the Institutional Theory with references of Rowan, Tolbert, and Zucker and finally, we will review some of the theoretical issues found in this theory. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Institutionalism is complex and covers many fields like

  22. Systematic review of institutional innovation literature: towards a

    The aim of this article is to review existing literature on institutional innovation based on a systematic approach. The review examines the trends of research methodologies and theories in studies, analyses key determinants, and synthesises management priorities for institutional innovation. ... with institutional theory, rather unsurprisingly ...

  23. A systematic review of the knowledge domain of institutional theory in

    However, only a few conceptual papers have been published thus far, and a literature review is needed to identify how that knowledge domain has developed. Based on the results of bibliometric analysis and content analysis, this study proposes potential future avenues for institutional theory in construction project management (ITCPM) studies.

  24. Tax morale and institutional theory: a systematic review

    A large range of random explanatory variables identified in the literature as determinants of tax morale are synthesised and structured by drawing inspiration from the institutional theory.,To do this, a systematic search has been conducted using a library catalogue which provides access to more than 400 databases.,The finding is that the ...

  25. An extended institutional theory perspective on the adoption of

    CE literature uses institutional theory to expla include environmental reporting practices (Dagiliene et al., 2020), ... First, the literature review revealed the lack of prior knowledge in this specific research stream, which made an exploratory case method ideal for our study (Eisenhardt and Graebner, ...

  26. Criticism in opposition: review of Epistemology of Communication in

    Extract. Started about a decade ago, Francisco Rüdiger has developed a contestation project in relation to the work of a group of Brazilian communicologists which, in 2022, is sanctioned in the work Epistemologia da Comunicação no Brasil: ensaios críticos sobre teoria da ciência [Epistemology of Communication in Brazil: critical essays on science theory].